12/27/20

We have validated our model allowing for an accurate prediction of GDP growth using unemployment estimates

 According to the gap version of Okun’s law, there exists a negative relation between the output gap, (Yp-Y)/Yp, where Yp is potential output at full employment and Y is actual output, and the deviation of the actual unemployment rate, u, from its natural rate, un. The overall GDP or output includes the change in population as an extensive component which is not necessary dependent on other macroeconomic variables. Econometrically, it is mandatory to use macroeconomic variables of the same origin and dimension. Therefore, we use real GDP per capita, G, and rewrite Okun’s law in the following form: 

            du = a + bdlnG                                   (1) 

where du is the change in the rate of unemployment per unit time (say, 1 year); dlnG=dG/G is the relative change rate in real GDP per capita, a and b are empirical coefficients.  Okun’s law implies b<0.

The intuition behind Okun’s law is very simple.  Everybody may feel that the rate of unemployment is likely to rise when real economic growth is very low or negative. An economy needs fewer employees to produce the same or smaller real GDP also because of labor productivity growth.

When integrated between t0 and t, equation (1) can be rewritten in the following form: 

ut = u0 + bln[Gt/G0] + a(t-t0)  + c          (2) 

where ut is the rate of unemployment at time t. The intercept c≡0, as is clear for t=t0.  Instead of using the continuous form (2), we calculate a cumulative sum of the annual estimates of dlnG with appropriate initial conditions. By definition, the cumulative sum of the observed du’s is the time series of the unemployment rate, ut. Statistically, the use of levels, i.e. u and G, instead of their differentials are superior due to suppression of uncorrelated measurement errors.  

We showed (Kitov, 2011) the necessity of structural breaks in (1). Therefore, we introduced floating structural breaks in (2), which years have to be determined by the best fit. Thus, relationship (2) should be split into N segments. The integral form of Okun’s law should be also split into N time segments:

 ut = u0    + b1ln[Gt/G0]       + a1(t-t0),    t<ts1                                                                                      

ut = us1   + b2ln[Gt/Gts1]    + a2(t-ts1),    ts2≥t ≥ts1

ut = usN-1 + bNln[Gt/GtsN-1] + aN(t-tsN-1), tsN≥t ≥tsN-1              (3) 

In 2011, we started with the U.S. The LSQR method applied to the integral form of Okun’s law (3) results in the following relationship:           

dup = -0.406dlnG + 1.113, 1979>t≥1951

dup = -0.465dlnG + 0.866, 2010≥t≥1979                (4) 

where dup is the predicted annual increment in the rate of unemployment, dlnG is the relative change rate in real GDP per capita per year. A structural break around 1979 was found. It divides the whole 60-year interval into two practically equal segments. Figure 1 displays the measured and predicted rate of unemployment in the U.S. since 1951. The agreement between these curves is excellent with a standard error of 0.55%. The average rate of unemployment for the same period is 5.75% with a mean annual increment of 1.1%.  This is a very accurate model of unemployment with R2=0.89. Hence, our model (the integral Okun’s law) explains 89% of the variability in the rate of unemployment between 1951 and 2010 with the model residual most likely related to measurement errors.  Statistically, there is not much room for any other variables to influence the rate of unemployment, except they are affecting the real GDP per capita. 

Figure 1.  The observed and predicted rate of unemployment in the USA between 1951 and 2010. 

Our initial model worked well and its performance can be further validated by new data. Almost ten years passed and now we have two excellent opportunities to check the model: new readings for the previous years since 2010 and the extremely deep fall in the real GDP per capita accompanied by the unprecedented growth in the rate of unemployment in the USA, both induced by the COVID-19 pandemic. The latter is a dynamic effect of an exogenous and non-economic force. This is the best test of the link between the real GDP per capita and the unemployment rate. 

In our previous post, we supposed that the years between 2010 and 2019 have to be used to estimate the regression coefficient after the 2010 break. This structural break is related to the change in real GDP definition as one can see in Figure 2 from our previous post. In the upper panel of Figure 2 we present the evolution of the cumulative inflation (the sum of annual inflation rates) as defined by the CPI and dGDP between 1971 and 2020. Both variables are normalized to their respective values in 1970.  In the middle panel, the dGDP cumulative inflation is multiplied by a factor of 1.26 after 1979. The deviation since 1979 might be induced by a break in the GDP time series according to the comprehensive NIPA revision. After 2010, the CPI and dGDP curves still deviate, however. This effect is observed in new data and is likely associated with another break in the GDP time series. In the lower panel, we use a new coefficient of 0.8 in order to fit the CPI and dGDP after 2010. The overall fit is good and the total factor for this period is 0.8*1.26=1.00. It seems the old GDP definition is used after 2010.  



Figure 2. Upper panel: The evolution of the cumulative inflation (the sum of annual inflation rates) as defined by the CPI and dGDP between 1971 and 2020. Both variables are normalized to their respective values in 1970.  Middle panel: The dGDP cumulative inflation is multiplied by a factor of 1.26 after 1979. This deviation is induced by a break in the GDP time series according to the comprehensive NIPA revision). After 2010, the CPI and dGDP curves still deviate. This effect is observed in new data and is likely associated with another break in GDP time series. Lower panel: A new coefficient of 0.8 is used to fit the CPI and dGDP after 2010. The fit is good and the total factor for this period is 0.8*1.26=1.00. It seems the old GDP definition is used after 2010.   

The main result of our meticulous inspection of the CPI and dGDP deviation is the presence of breaks in data (i.e. data is not compatible in time) due to major revisions to the real GDP definition. Such a break was used in our version of Okun’s law for the USA as described by equation (4). The 2010 break may extend equation (3) to three different segments: 1951 to 1979, 1980 to 2010, and after 2010, with three different sets of coefficients. When the 1979-to-2010 set of coefficients is applied to the data after 2010 one obtains the curve shown in Figure 3, which does not match the measured rate of unemployment. Therefore, we apply the standard LSQR procedure to estimate a new set of coefficients for the period after 2010. The preliminary analysis gives the following model:           

dup = -0.406dlnG + 1.122, 1979>t≥1951

dup = -0.465dlnG + 0.899, 2010≥t≥1979       

dup = -0.260dlnG  - 0.250,           t≥2010                 (5) 

Figure 4 illustrates the model predictive power. In the upper panel, the measured rate of unemployment in the USA between 1951 and 2019 is compared with the rate predicted by model (5) with the real GDP per capita published by the BEA. The rate of unemployment is borrowed from the BLS. In the middle panel, the model residual errors are presented with a standard deviation of 0.49% and the mean unemployment rate of 5.8%. The lower panel depicts the linear regression of the measured and predicted time series with Rsq.=0.89. Hence, the new set of coefficients provides an excellent match between the measured and predicted values, i.e. the model linking the change in the unemployment rate and the change in real GDP per capita is validated by the data between 2010 and 2019.

Figure 3. When the 1979-to-2010 set of coefficients is applied to the data after 2010 the predicted curve does not match the measured one.

Figure 4. Upper panel: The measured rate of unemployment in the USA between 1951 and 2019 and the rate predicted by model (5) with the real GDP per capita published by the BEA. Middle panel: The model residual. Lower panel: linear regression of the measured and predicted time series. Rsq = 0.89.  

The ultimate validation test would be the model prediction for 2020, when the rate of unemployment changes by 10%  per quarter and the real GDP per capita falls by 35% in one quarter and then jumps back by 30%. It will be our next step after we present the prediction obtained using the MPD estimates of the real GDP per capita. Figure 5 shows that the MPD gives a slightly better fit with Rsq=0.91. This is just marginal improvement but it is important in terms of the methodology of statistical estimates with not perfect data measurements.  Finally, Figure 6 presents the rate of unemployment predicted for the three quarters of 2020. The spike in the second quarter is extremely accurately predicted with the model (5) estimated for the period between 2010 and in 2019. It is a good indicator that the model is still applicable and there were no NIPA revisions. 

Interestingly, the third quarter demonstrates a large prediction error – 5.3% instead of the measured value of 8.8%. The predicted unemployment rate is obtained with the real GDPpc growth of 30% in the third quarter.  The first GDP estimates for the third quarter might be highly overestimated. If the measured value of 8.8% is correct, the GDPpc growth has to be only 17% from the previous quarter.  We will follow the BEA releases with updated GDP estimates as well as the BLS releases with new estimates of the unemployment rate. The fourth quarter and the whole of 2020 is the next challenge for our Okun’s law version. 

In any case, one can use the unemployment estimates for an accurate prediction of the GDP growth!

 

Figure 5. Same as in Figure 4 with the MPD estimates of the real GDPpc.  

 

Figure 6. The rate of unemployment predicted for three quarters of 2020. The spike in the second quarter is extremely accurately predicted with the model (5) for the period after 2010. The third quarter demonstrates a large discrepancy, but the first GDP estimates might be highly inaccurate.   

No comments:

Post a Comment