11. Mean
income for males and females as reported by the Census Bureau
Figure 1. The
evolution of mean income (real 2013 U.S. dollars) since 1967 (Source: Census
Bureau, http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/income/data/historical/people/2013/p09AR.xls,
downloaded, July 10, 2015)
Figure 2. Mean income as a function of age for the
year of 2013. Income is in 2013 US dollars.
Two important features – lower mean incomes for females and earlier
(age) peak value for female.
Figure 3. The age of peak mean income evolves in time.
When normalized to the peak value in a given year the mean income dependence on
age shifts to higher age for both male and female.
Figure 4. The age of peak mean income for female lags
by about 30 years behind the peak age for males.
22. Median
income for males and females as reported by the Census Bureau
Figure 5. Same effect is observed for median income –
the lag is about 30 years.
33. The
distribution of population with income above the Pareto threshold ($100,000)
Figure 6. The
number of people with income above $100,000 in 2013 as a function of age for
male and female population. Total male and female population is 122,414,000 and
129,930,000, respectively. When the
distribution of personal capacity and sizes of instruments is the same for male
and female, one should expect the blue curve above the red one.
Figure 7. The
evolution of the number of people above the Pareto threshold with time. For a
direct comparison, all four curves for 2013 and 1994 are normalized to their
respective peaks. Despite low accuracy of measurements one can observed that
the peak age value for female is lower than for male. Male and female
distributions both shift to higher age with time.
Figure 8. Same
as in Figure 7 for the years of 1974 and 2013.
The peak age in 1974 is around 30 years and 55 years in 2013.
44. Personal
income distribution
Figure 9.
Personal income distributions for male, female and both genders in 2013. The
exponent for the Pareto distribution of female is practically the same as for
male.
Figure 10. When corrected
to the change in real GDP (1.23) and male population (106,910,000 and
122,4141,000) between 2001 and 2013, the
relevant PIDs coincide. As a consequence, the Gini ratio does not change in
time, as reported by the CB.
Figure 11. When
corrected to the change in real GDP (0.86) the female’s PID for 2013 coincides
with the male’s PID for 2001. Therefore, the female’s PID lags behind the male
PID by the number of years related to the growth in real GDP per capita by 1/0.86=
1.16. The male population increasing by 1% per year makes this lag even larger.
We estimate the male’s PID from the year of 1975 to 1985 to fit the female’s
PID in 2013. The lag is still about 30 years.
Discussion
Our model easily
explains all observed features by one cause – the female population has the
same distribution of the capability to earn money (aka human capital) and
consistently low sizes of work instruments (work capital) compared to those for
men. Considering the same capability to earn money for females, one can
conclude that the relatively lower work capitals (e.g. job positions, assets,
…) are controlled by force (likely by the other gender). Fair distribution has not been achieved yet.
The relative
lower instrument sizes given to females make the proportion of female above the
Pareto threshold lower. In turn this effect lowers the mean income for the same
age since a relatively lower number of rich female occurs in all age groups.
The faster
income growth and the earlier age peak in the Pareto distribution for females
indicates that their higher capacities were applied to smaller instruments
(capital) in line with the deprivation of higher instrument sizes (capitals) of
the female population.
The forced deprivation of higher job positions
(working capital) is the cause of the observed long term income inequality between
male and female in the US.
No comments:
Post a Comment