Introduction
This study is devoted to cross country comparison of
specific characteristics related to personal income distribution (PID). Not all
countries provide open access to their estimates of income obtained from
surveys, tax and administrative records. The U.S. has likely the best system of
income measurements and the longest historic time series, with almost all data
(except may be data in the highest income range) available in digital format
from various governmental agencies, private companies, and universities. For
the U.S., we have already presented select results of the comprehensive study
conducted since 2003 [1,2]. There are two
characteristics which best express the evolution of personal income
distribution (PID) with age and time. First characteristic is related to the mean income dependence on age which evolves in time following up the increasing
real GDP per capita. The age of peak mean income grows as the root square of
the real GDP per capita and this phenomenon in clearly observed in the personal
income data published by the U.S. Census Bureau since 1947. A similar feature
is observed in the dependence on age of the proportion of people with the
highest incomes, which in the second
characteristic of the PID in the U.S.
Both studied dependencies on age provide the level of
income aggregation which best balances the clarity of observed changes and
suppression of larger fluctuations related to numerous revisions to survey
questionnaires (i.e. revisions to personal income definition) and the accuracy
of measurements themselves. For example, while two studied characteristics demonstrate
well measurable changes, the estimated values of Gini ratio for the CPS
personal incomes has just marginal fluctuation between 0.50 and 0.52 since 1962
[2]. We use the CPS data for people with reported income to calculate a
consistent time series for this ratio for the whole period between 1947 and
2014. At the same time, the level of fluctuations observed in the original
microdata is so high that there is no explanation of the observed changes in
narrow age and income bins for sequential years.
Therefore, the dependence of mean income and proportion of people with
the highest incomes on age provides reliable measures of the evolutionary
behavior and robust statistical inferences related to the driving force behind
this evolution. The U.S. data gives the best and longest historical prospective
of time and age dependent processes in the personal income distribution.
However, there is always a question about the universal character of the
observed evolution with real GDP per capita. This study answers this question
to the extent limited by the availability and accuracy of personal income data.
(We are going to proceed with new dataset when available.) On the whole, we
give a positive answer – the dependence of mean income and the proportion of
people with the highest incomes on age as observed in the USA is reproduced one-to-one
(considering data accuracy) in Canada, New Zealand, and the UK. The curves
observed in these three countries repeat those observed in the U.S. for the
years when the level real GDP per capita was the same. This observation seems
to prove that the evolution of personal income (at least in these four
countries) follows the same path, i.e. this is a universal characteristic
related the only driving force - real GDP per capita.
1. Personal income definition
We
start with a slightly provocative statement that there exists no comprehensive
and accurate definition of personal income, which can be used for a true
estimate of age/gender/race-dependent properties. There are several operational
definitions of personal income measuring different portions of the true
personal income, the definition of which does not exist so far. Having no
genuine income values one is forced to use only available data. In such a
situation, the accuracy and coherency of sequential estimates are two most
important issues. To conduct a reliable quantitative analysis, one can use any
constant portion of the true value and get almost the same predictive power of
the obtained relationships as that obtained from the true value itself. For
example, a voltmeter accurately measures a voltage using just a small portion
of total electric current.
When
several sources of data are available it is worth to compare how similar are
the features we study as estimated from different datasets. For example, do they
reveal the same dependence of mean income on age? This is important aspect of
the study by itself since it provides a reasonable constraint on data accuracy.
In a cross country comparison, it is especially important because the datasets
reported by countries may have different sources. For example, the UK provides
an extensive set of income time series based on tax data, while New Zealand
publishes the results of annual income surveys conducted in the second quarter
of each year. For the U.S. both sets are available and thus it is a
straightforward task to compare them before we study other countries.
Figure
1 schematically compares the personal income estimates as reported by three agencies,
which provide related statistics: the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), the
Census Bureau (CB), and the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). The BEA has been
reporting accurate aggregate estimates of the total personal income (PI) and
its distribution over major sources (e.g., wage and salary, contributions
for employee pension and insurance funds, personal income receipts on assets,
etc.) since 1929. With all important procedures, tools and estimates allowing tight
control over other sources of income data, the BEA does not provide fine
structure of the personal income distribution in the USA. For the purposes of
our study, it does not report age, gender and race distribution of personal
incomes. This set of personal data cannot be used. In Figure 1, only the ratio
of total personal income (PI) and Gross Domestic Income (GDI=GDP) since 1947 is
presented. In the year of 1947, the annual income surveys in the U.S. were
started.
The
Internal Revenue Service provides the longest time series of income data – some
variables begin in 1913. Figure 1 depicts two time series related to the IRS.
The number of individual tax returns (a proxy to the number of people) is
divided by the total working age population (age 15 and above) for the same
year and represents the portion of people with income. In the 1950s and 1960s,
the proportion of people with (IRS) income was between 50% and 52%. In the
2000s and 2010s, this proportion was between 57% and 60%. The total income
reported to the IRS, which is called Adjusted Gross Income (AGI) is divided by
the GDI and represents the portion of personal income (according to the IRS
definition) in the GDI. The BEA carries out annual inspections of all incomes
included in the AGI and reports very specific errors in the IRS statistics. For
example, the gap between the AGI estimate reported by the NIPA (National Income
and Product Accounts) and that of the IRS reached 15% in 2005. This gap puts
some constraint on the accuracy of the IRS personal income estimates.
Unfortunately, these errors are aggregated. They are not distributed over age
and so on.
There
are several income time series reported by the IRS, which can be used in our
study. They include the number of people in finite bins extended to $10,000,000.
This is a very high income in comparison with the current level of $250,000 in
the CPS, which is, however, reported only from the mid-2000s. The IRS datasets
are of crucial importance for estimating the properties of the highest incomes
distribution, i.e. the portion of people above some high threshold. The Pareto
law implies that the PID above such a threshold should follow up the power law.
In addition, the income distribution in five-year age bins (and for two
genders) is published for the year of 1998. Similar distributions for ten-year
bins are available for the years between 2008 and 2012.
Figure 1. The proportion of
people with income reported by the Census Bureau from the Current Population
Surveys (CPS) and the number of returns reported by the Internal revenue
Service (IRS) in the total working age population. The proportion of total
personal income reported by the CB and IRS in the Gross Domestic Income
(GDI=GDP). For comparison of various definition, the estimate of personal income
estimate (PI) reported by the Bureau of Economic Analysis is shown.
The
Census Bureau provides the finest distributions of personal income over
numerous parameters. The Census Bureau uses the mechanism of annual Current Population Surveys to measure
personal incomes in approximately 80,000 households. In order to map this
smaller population subset to the entire U.S. population the CB uses the age-gender-race
dependent scaling coefficients for each person in the CPS. By construction,
this approach has much lower measurement accuracy for underrepresented
categories. For example, young black females with higher incomes have very low
probability to be present in the CPS. Sometimes, one or two persons represent
the whole population in the same age-gender-race category. As a consequence,
larger fluctuations are observed in the related distributions. In Figure 1, the
portion of population with income (as reported in the CPS) in the total working
age population is presented together with the portion of the CPS total income
in the GDI. The total CPS income is also the estimate obtained from the 80,000
households and then scaled to the whole population. In 2012, the CPS population
universe presumably included approximately 87% people with income; the IRS gave
only 57%. At the same time, the figure of total personal income reported by the
CB was about 57% of the GDI, i.e. the same as reported by the IRS. The CB has a
quite specific definition of personal income: “CPS money income is defined as
total pre-tax cash income earned by persons, excluding certain lump sum
payments and excluding capital gains”, while “BEA personal income is the income
received by persons from participation in production, from government and
business transfer payments, and from government interest.TP 1 PT BEA estimates
personal income largely from administrative data sources” (Ruser et al., 2004). Therefore, the CB’s personal income estimates are
also known as “CPS money income”. It is important that larger part of the
difference between the CB’s and BEA’s estimates (around 25% of the CB’s income)
can be explained by the differences in income sources. The error in wage and
salary estimates (underreporting) in the CPS can reach 5% to 10% of the total
CPS income.
This
is the level of accuracy of personal income data we have to work with. In
addition, the IRS dataset has a significant problem with the population
coverage. The proportion of people with income not only relatively small but
also varies with time. Together with the observed high-amplitude oscillations
in the AGI the variations in the number of returns induces measureable
fluctuations in the high-level estimates of inequality (e.g. the Gini ratio) e,
with the less aggregated measures of personal income experiencing even larger
disturbances. In this sense, the CPS data set has clear advantages since all
income estimates are scaled to the whole population. As a consequence, the
measures of income inequality are not changing much due to data inconsistency
over time.
Detailed
comparison of the PIDs reported by the IRS and CB is beyond the scope of this
study. Merging of the IRS high-income data and CPS low-income estimates is a
delicate issue and deserves a special study, which may result is a more
reliable time series based on a more precise definition of personal income.
Here, we compare only one of the characteristics under investigation – the
evolution of mean income with age. Figure 2 displays the distribution of people
and income over age as reported by the CPS and IRS for the year of 1998. This
is the only year when the age dependent mean income is reported by the IRS in
narrower age bins. For the years between 2008 and 2012, the IRS reported mean
incomes in age bins incompatible with those used by the CB. The CPS counts more
people in all age bins and larger total incomes everywhere.
Dividing the total income by the number of people in a given age bin we
obtain an estimate of mean income. Figure 3 depicts various mean income curves
as reported by the IRS and Census Bureau. To present the CPS data, we use three
different data sets. The IPUMS provides the original income measurements (microdata),
which allow calculation of mean incomes in one-year bins. The resulting curve
in Figure 3 is characterized by visible fluctuations, which are especially
large near the peak mean income. Therefore, these estimates are not helpful for
accurate comparison with the IRS data. The mean income reported by the CB in five-year
bins (see Table PINC-01. Selected Characteristics of
People 15 Years and Over, by Total Money Income in 1998, Work Experience in
1998) provides the best case comparison with the IRS data, while the mean
income distribution in ten-year bins may cause some problem in the estimation
of the age corresponding to the peak mean income.
Figure 3 reveals the difference in income sources used by the CPS and
IRS. The Census Bureau reports higher mean incomes for the youngest and eldest
population. At the same time, the IRS mean income is higher for ages between 40
and 65 years. The largest difference is observed near the peak mean income. Despite
the discrepancy in the IRS and CPS curves, the most important observation is
that the age when these curves reach their peak values are very close. To
better illustrate the coincidence of peaks in the mean income distribution we
normalized all curves to their peak values. Figure 4 displays two curves for
five-year bins and also presents the curve obtained from the IPUMS microdata
but now smoothed with a centred nine-year moving average – MA(9). All three
curves are characterized by peak at 52.5 years. This is the age of the largest
mean income in 1998. As we know, the peak age in the U.S. has been increasing
with real GDP per capita and was above 55 years in 2012.
In this Section, we demonstarte that income estimates provided by the Census Bureau and IRS are close in dimensionless representation. This result is valuable for further comparison of income data obtained by various agencies in different countries. For example, we assume that the similarity of CPS and IRS data in the U.S. allows us to compare tax-related data reported by the UK for a given year and some CPS data twenty to thirty years earlier.
Figure 2.
The number of people (upper panel) and total income (lower panel) in five-year
bins (except the bin between 15 and 24 years of age) as reported by the IRS and
CPS for the year of 1998.
Figure 3. The mean income as a
function of age as reported by the Census Bureau (CPS) and the Internal Revenue
Service (IRS) for 1998. This is the only year with a fine (five-year age bins)
age-dependent personal income distribution reported by the IRS. For comparison,
we use the set of microdata published by the IPUMS for 1998. To illustrate the
difference in the presentation of income in various bins, the mean income curve
based on ten-year bins borrowed from the CB historical dataset is also shown.
The mean income for the youngest and eldest age groups is higher than that
reported by the IRS. Between 40 and 65 years of age, the IRS mean income is
higher.
Figure 4. The IRS
and CPS microdata curves in Figure 3 are normalized to their peak values. The
age of peak mean income is the same for the CPS and IRS.
2.
Cross country
comparison
2.1.
GDP per capita
The main
assumption of our study is the dependence of some aggregated properties of personal
income distribution only on real GDP per capita. This implies that countries
with lower GDP per capita have to repeat PID features observed in the countries
with higher GDP per capita. To compare different countries we borrowed real GDP
per capita estimates from the Total Economy
Database
(TED) operated by the
Conference Board. Figure
5 displays the evolution of real GDP per capita in the USA, UK, Canada, and New
Zealand as expressed in 1990 US$ converted at Geary Khamis PPPs. As we assume
that the accuracy of income measurement has been increasing with time the most
recent estimates for the latter three countries likely have some advantages to
be used for a reliable cross country comparison.
In Figure 5, three
horizontal dotted lines show the level of GDP per capita in some country
specific year between 2011 and 2014. Their intersections
with the USA curve provide the years when the US personal income presumably had
the same aggregated characteristics. For example, real GDP per capita in the UK
was $23,272 in 2012. In the USA, approximately the same level was observed in
1992 ($23,363). For New Zealand, the estimate of $20,526 in 2014 gives 1985 as the
matching year. In Canada, the level of $25,400 in 2011 corresponds to that
measured in the USA in 1996. One has to take into account that the PPP values are
subject to revision and may not be accurate for some countries and years. Moreover,
the PPP curves may differ dramatically from those expressed in domestic
currency. Then a problem arises which of two estimates is better to use for our
cross country comparison.
Figure 5. The evolution of real
GDP per capita in 1990 US$ (converted at Geary Khamis PPPs) as borrowed from
the Total Economy Database reported by
the Conference Board.
Cross comparison of the dynamics of personal income evolution in four (English
speaking) developed countries for which we have retrieved data from open
sources – Canada, New Zealand, the UK, and the USA. Three horizontal dotted
lines show the level of GDP per capita in three countries in some
country-specific years between 2011and 2014 and their intersections with the USA curve provide the
years when the US personal income presumably had the same characteristics.
2.2. The United Kingdom
The
United Kingdom is the first country to compare with the U.S. All income-related
tables were borrowed from “Distribution of
median and mean income and tax by age range and gender”, which is a
part of the UK Government portal. The
age-dependent income data are obtained from the Survey of Personal Incomes (SPI), an annual sample survey
carried out by HM
Revenue & Customs. The income tables include
only information on
individuals liable to UK income tax, i.e. sources of income are restricted to
tax purposes only. Therefore, the UK income tables are better to be compared to
those reported by the U.S. IRS. In paragraph 2.1, we found that the level real
GDP per capita in the UK lags by about 20 years behind that measured in the
USA. Under our framework, the shape of the age-dependent mean income curves
depends only on real GDP per capita. Then the U.S. curve to compare to the 2012
UK mean income is that for 1992. Since the data on the years before 1993 are
not available from the IRS we have to use the CPS income tables. Such a
replacement may introduce some distortions in matching process. However, as shown
in Section 1, the IRS and CPS estimates of peak mean income age are very close.
We start with
the time history of age-dependent mean income in the UK, which is confined to the years between 1999 and 2012, since
the original tables (1999-2000 through 2012-2013) are available only for this
period.
There
are no estimates for 2008 as the relevant table is not published. Figure 6
presents the evolution of age-dependent (nominal) mean income (expressed in
GBP) with time. The presented curves are obtained as spline interpolations
between actual estimates in 5-year age bins. The shape of these curves is
similar to that observed in the U.S. – quasi-logarithmic growth to the peak
value and then quasi-exponential fall. The age of transition from growth to
fall, i.e. the age of peak mean
income, has been increasing with time. If the shape of the mean income curve
depends only on real GDP per capita the age of peak in the UK has to follow up
the same trajectory as in the U.S., with the GDP per capita as defining
parameter.
Figure 6. The evolution of
age-dependent mean income between 1999 and 2012. No estimates are available for
2008. The absence is likely related to the 2008 financial crisis. The mean
income values are assigned to the midpoints of 5-year bins as shown by circles
in the 1999 curve. Age is replaced by work experience. The 2012 curve is above
all other curved everywhere. The 1999 curve is the lowermost one except in the
large work experience range. Three curves between 2001 and 2003 are very close
to each other. Almost all curves are characterized by local fluctuations in the
bin between 45 and 49 years of work experience. The curves between 2005 and
2007 are smooth, however.
For the purpose
of quantitative analysis, age is replaced by work experience. By definition,
personal work experience is equal to the age of a given person less 14 years.
The mean income estimates are assigned to the midpoints of the respective work
experience bins, as shown for the 1999 curve in Figure 6. The only exception is
the youngest and open-ended population bin “under 20 years of age”, where no
midpoint can be assigned. In Figure 6, we assign the corresponding mean income
value to 2 years of work experience by force and use this estimate only for
illustration. The 2012 curve is above all other curves everywhere. The 1999
curve is the lowermost one except in the large work experience range. Three
curves between 2001 and 2003 are very close to each other. Almost all curves are
characterized by local fluctuations of varying amplitude in the bin between 45
and 49 years of work experience. The curves between 2005 and 2007 are smooth,
however. The cause of this difference is not clear and we do not consider all
possible deviations between the UK and U.S. mean income curves in this age
range.
Since individual
incomes in different countries are measure in domestic currency one cannot
carry out a direct comparison of mean income curves. Scaling to some common
currency (e.g. USD) is possible at, say, PPP conversion rates, but in terms of
shape comparison this procedure would not differ from the normalization of the
mean income curves to their respective maximum values. This was a standard
procedure in comparison of U.S. incomes for the period between 1947 and 2011 (Kitov and Kitov,
2013)
and we have applied in to the UK data. Figure 7 displays the same curves as in
Figure 6 but normalized to their respective peak values. There are two clear
observations – the work experience corresponding to the peak mean income
increases with time (actually GDP per capita) and the 2012 curve now lies below
all other curves before the peak value and above after the peak work
experience. We call the age (work experience) corresponding to the peak mean
income “critical age” or “bifurcation point” since the behaviour of the mean
income curve changes from quasi-logarithmic growth to exponential fall. In this
point, the process of income distribution suffers some dramatic changes, and
this is not the age of retirement. In the U.S., the critical age was measured
between 35 and 40 years of age seventy years ago and currently approaches 60.
Figure 7. Same curves as in
Figure 6 with all mean income estimates normalized to the peak mean incomes for
the respective years. The growth in the work experience corresponding to the
peak value is clearly seen.
In order to
estimate the age of peak mean income, Figure 8 presents the central segments of
the curves in Figure 7. The normalization procedure results in dimensionless
estimates of the average income assigned to the midpoints of the corresponding
age bins. The lines drawn through these estimates do not represent actual
values of dimensionless mean income except in the midpoints. They are spline
interpolations of these estimated values, with the age of the maximum value in
the obtained curves likely to be shifted from the midpoint of the bin with the
peak value. (Therefore, some curves may be above 1.0.) These estimated maxima
are then used to evaluate the shift in the age-dependence mean income. In
Figure 8, the 1999 curve (thick blue line) has a larger work experience peak (around
31 years) than the peak age for 2000 and 2001 (dotted lines) - between 28 and
29 years, as well as for 2002 and 2003 (dashed lines) – around 30 years. The
curves between 2004 and 2011 are characterized by a gradual increase in the
peak age, with the 2012 curve (black line) peaking at approximately 32.5 years
of work experience. Therefore, the 1999 curve likely includes some biased
estimates and we do not use it in the following quantitative estimates.
Figure 8. The age (work
experience) of peak mean income increases with real GDP per capita. The 1999
curve (thick blue line) has a larger work experience peak than those for 2000 and
2001 (dotted lines) around 28 years, as well as for 2002 and 2003 (dashed
lines) – around 30 years. The curves between 2004 and 2011 are characterized by
gradual increase in the peak age. The 2012 curve (black line) peaks at 32.5
years. Therefore, the 1999 curve likely includes some biased estimates.
Figure
8 demonstrates the evolution of the normalized curves and proves that the work
experience corresponding to the peak mean income increases from approximately 28-29
years in 2000 and 2001 to above 32 years in 2012-2013. The estimates of real
GDP per capita are $20,207 and $23,017 in 2000 and 2012, respectively. Theoretically,
the working experience should increase from 28.5 years to 28.5√(23017/20207)=30.9
years. The estimates of average disposable income reported by the OECD give a
slightly larger age growth between 2000 and 2012 - 2.7 years. So, the assumed
root square dependence suggests that the theoretical difference between the
peak ages has to be approximately 2.4 to 2.7 years. Considering the accuracy of
the peak age and GDP/income measurements, the match between the predicted
increase of 2 to 3 years and the observed one of approximately 4 years is a
good one. For better estimate, one needs a much longer and more accurate time
series.
Historically, population in the UK
needs more and more time to reach the peak mean income. According to our
microeconomic model (Kitov
and Kitov, 2013), this effect is caused by
increasing sizes of work capital, with the growth proportional to the root
square of the real GDP per capita, similar to the Cobb-Douglas production
function. This allows higher personal incomes (as well as real GDP per capita)
to be achieved by all individuals in a given economy. Basically, the mechanism
allowing getting higher incomes consists in decreasing discounting factor
counteracting income growth. For a given person, the rate of income discounting
is proportional to the attained level of income and inversely proportional to
the size of work capital applied by this person. Mathematically, this term
leads to a slower relative discounting for incomes earned with the largest work
capitals.
One negative outcome of the increasing real GDP per capita
is that the relative share of income in the youngest age group is subject to
gradual decrease, which is inevitable in the current system of economic and
social ties. Figure 9 presents the evolution of the normalized mean income in
all age groups; the group “under 20” is not shown. Three youngest
age groups: 5 to 9, 10 to 14, and 15 to 19 years of work experience, are
characterized by a falling proportion of their mean income since 1999. This
trend cannot be reversed in the future if real GDP per capita will be growing. Between
2000 and 2003, the peak work experience shifted from the 25 to 29 years bin to
the 30 to 34 years bin. Such a transition happens not often and we are lucky to
find it in the UK data. The next transition will be to the 35-39 years bin. One
can observe that the proportion of mean income has been also increasing in this
group. The peak mean income will likely move into this age group in the next 10
to 15 years, depending on real GDP growth. The proportion of mean income in the
elder categories has been increasing
as well. The
25-29 years of work experience group lost the peak and joined the category of
younger population.
Figure 9. The evolution of mean
income in all 5-year age groups normalized to the peak value in the same
year. In three youngest age groups (7, 12, and 17 years of work experience),
the proportion of mean income has been falling since 1999. The peak work
experience shifted from the 25 to 29 years bin to the 30 to 34 years bin
between 2000 and 2003. The proportion of mean income has been increasing in the
group between 35 and 39 years. The peak will likely move into this age group in
the next 10 to 15 years, depending on real GDP growth. The proportion of mean
income in the elder categories has been increasing as well.
The increasing
age of mean income peak and the decreasing income portion of the youngest
population observed in the UK both confirm similar features observed in the
mean income distribution in the USA. Therefore, the evolution of personal
income distribution in the UK likely follows the same dependence on age as in
the USA. As discussed above, in case this dependence is, mathematically, a
universal one, the curves in Figure 7 have to repeat similar curves observed in
the U.S. in the years defined by GDP per capita.
In paragraph
2.1, we have evaluated that the UK curve for 2012-2013 has to match the U.S.
curve for 1992. For this comparison, we used income microdata published by the
IPUMS. As before, we have smoothed the annual mean income estimates with a
centred MA(9). Figure 10 is the key evidence in favour of universal character
of the mean income dependence on real GDP per capita. Despite all differences
in sources of data and measuring procedures the shapes of two curves, separated
by 20 years full of economic, social, demographic and so on processes and
events in the UK as well as country boarders and the intrinsic difference in
all aspects of life between the UK and USA, is practically identical! In order highlight the level of
similarity between these two curves we added two lines corresponding to 1991
and 1993 in the USA. The 1991 curve deviates from the UK curve, while the 1993
curve is very similar to the 1992 curve. The GDP per capita estimates are
$22,875, $23,363, and $23,690 in 1991, 1992, and 1993, respectively. Unfortunately,
we do not have any IRS data for 1992. The small discrepancy in two curves in
Figure 10 between 25 and 29 years of age could have the same cause as the
deviation in Figure 3 – the IRS mean income for younger ages is smaller than
that measured by the Census Bureau.
Figure 10.
Comparison of the UK mean income curve for 2012-2013 and that observed in the
USA in 1992. Microdata provided by the IPUMS are used.
Figure 11.
Comparison of the UK mean income curve for 2000-2001 and that observed in the
USA in 1984.
For the earliest
reliable UK mean income curve (2000-2001) we found the best matching year as
well. This is the mean income curve for 1984. Figure 11 compares two
corresponding UK and U.S. curves and demonstrates almost the same level of fit.
The only difference – two curves deviate at ages above 55. According to the
Conference Board, the level of real GDP per capita in the UK in 2000 was
$20,207 (1990 US dollars). Almost the same figure was observed in the USA in
1984 - $20,122. Here, we have to stress that the time delay
in real GDP per capita between two compared countries plays no role for mean income
distributions. Time is just a parameter useful for indexing GDP measurements.
For the UK, we
have analysed a relatively short time series of the distribution of mean
(tax-related) income with age and found matching distributions in the much
longer CPS income dataset available for the USA. The most important result of
our analysis is the universal functional dependence of the aggregated income
characteristics on real GDP per capita. The UK GDP per capita is lagging by a
few thousand USD (in 2014, approximately $9000 as expressed in 1990 USD) behind
that for the USA. The shape of the current mean income distribution UK repeats
that observed in the earlier 1990s in the USA. This means that one can project
the evolution of the mean income distribution in the UK by $9000 ahead. This
makes 15 to 25 years depending on the annual growth in real GDP per capita.
Having the projection of major features in the personal income distribution one
can develop a wise socio-economic policy to mitigate the most damaging effects.
Projection beyond the current distribution in the USA is also possible since
the evolution of mean income is driven by real GDP per capita only.
For the UK, the
distribution of people over income is not available and we could not make any
estimation and comparison of the portion of people with higher income, which is
the second important indicator we use to characterize the increase in the age
when population of developed countries achieves the highest incomes. This
portion is most sensitive to age and real GDP per capita, especially in the
first few years of work experience. For the USA, we have already demonstrated these effects.
No comments:
Post a Comment