9/20/15

physical intuition behind income distribution

Here, a microeconomic model is presented, which has been developed to quantitatively describe the dynamics of personal income growth and distribution [Kitov, 2005a]. The model is based on one principal assumption that each and every individual above fifteen years of age has a personal capability to work. In essence, the capability to work is equivalent to the capability to earn money. To get money income, individuals have to use one or several means or tools from the full set of options that may includes paid job, government transfers, bank interest, capital gain, inter-family transfers, and others. The U.S. Census Bureau questionnaire [2006] includes tens of money income components. It is important to stress that some principle sources of income are not included in the CB definition, which results in the observed discrepancy between  aggregate (gross) personal income (GPI), as reported by the Bureau of Economic Analysis and the gross money income calculated by the CB.

In this section we summarize the formulation of a theoretical model, originally described in Kitov [2005a], and present it as a closed form solution in a simplified setting. Figure 1 illustrates a few general features any consistent model has to describe quantitatively. In the left panel, we display the evolution of mean income curves from 1962 to 2013. The original income data are borrowed from the IPUMS [2015]. These are income microdata, i.e. each and every person from the IPUMS tables is characterized (among other features) by age, gender, race, gross income, and the population weight, which allows projection the individuals from the CPS population universe to the entire population. Using age, income and population weight we have calculated the age dependent mean income for all years and then normalized them to their respective peak values. The normalized curves better illustrate the growth in the age of peak income – from below 40 in the earlier 1960s to 55 in the 2010s. This is a sizeable change likely expressing the work of inherent mechanisms driving the evolution of personal income distribution. One cannot neglect the effect of increasing age when people reach their peak incomes – neither from theoretical nor from the practical point of view.

In the right panel of Figure 1, we compare various mean income curves reported by two different organizations responsible for income measurements: the Census Bureau (CPS) and the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). The latter organization does not publish the age distribution of income at a regular basis and only the year of 1998 is available for such a comparison. The IRS mean income is calculated in 5-year age bins, the CPS prepares historical datasets with a 5-year granularity since 1993, and the annual estimates are available from the IPUMS microdata. The annual curve has also been smoothed with a nine-year moving average, MA(9). As in the left panel, all curves are normalized to their peak values.

There are significant differences in income sources and population coverage used by the CPS and IRS [Kitov, 2014]. Between 40 and 60 years of age, all curves in Figure 1 are close to each other. With regard to the age of peak income, the CPS and IRS give identical results to the extent the age aggregation allows. The IPUMS curve has been smoothed and thus might have a slightly biased peak age. Between 25 and 40 years of age, the difference in normalized mean income is larger likely because of the difference in income sources. Same effect is observed in the eldest age groups, where taxable incomes are not so often and the CPS curve is above the IRS one.

The closeness of the peak ages measured by the IRS and CPS is important for our consideration of the model applicability and reliability. The accuracy of income measurements, the coverage of population and income source, the level  of historical consistency in income definition and survey methodology, the diversity of personal characteristics, and the length of time series provided by the Census Bureau all these features make it inevitable to use the CPS data for quantitative modelling. The reverse side of this choice is the necessity to defend the modelling results against the accusation that the CPS data are not full and representative.

It is true that the CPS misses some important sources of higher incomes, but Figure 1 stresses that the estimates of key features are not be different if the IRS sources are included. Besides, the CB provides the best income estimates for the poorest population, where incomes are just several dollars per year. Other organizations ignore small incomes. As a result, the estimates of income inequality based on the IRS data exclude half of population, the poorest half. It is difficult to consider such estimates as accurate and helpful for understanding the mechanisms of income distribution. The BEA income data are absolutely worthless for quantitative analysis - no age, gender, race information is available.



 
Figure 1. Left panel: The change in the shape of mean income dependence on age from 1962 to 2013 as measured by the Census Bureau in the March Supplements of the Current Population Survey. All curves are normalized to their respective peak values. Right panel: Comparison of mean income dependence on age as measured by the Census Bureau (CPS) and the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). The only year with data available from the IRS is 1998.

It is very important to stress that the features observed in Figure 1 can be approximates by simple mathematical functions. Moreover, these functions represent solutions of simple ordinary differential equations. Solid red line in the right panel is calculated to fit the CPS mean income curve. For this line, the equation is [1 - exp(-0.071(t-15))] + 0.09, where t is the age. The overall fit between the measured and approximating curves is extremely good between 18 and 55 years of age, before the mean income curve starts to fall.

The approximating equation is a well-known function often called “exponential saturation function”. This function represents a closed-form solution of a simple ordinary differential equation dx(t)/dt=a-bx(t), where a>0 and b>0 are constants. The match between the observed and approximating curves provides some hint on the forces behind income growth. Second term in the above equation represents the force counteracting the unlimited growth of x(t).  The amplitude of the counteracting force is proportional to the attained level, and that implies the finite value of x(t)max
, t →∞.

A standard example in general physics to illustrate the saturation process is associated with heating of a metal ball by an internal source with constant power, W. The growth in temperature, T, is balanced by energy loss through the ball surface, and the energy flux through the surface is proportional to the attained temperature. Thermal conductivity can be treated as infinite in terms of the characteristic time of all other processes. For a ball of radius R and volumetric heat capacity, Cv, one can write the following equation: 
           
4/3πR3CvdT(t)/dt =  W – DT(t)4πR2                                                                            (1)

where D is a constant defining the efficiency of heat loss through the surface, which is similar to dissipation. By dividing both sides if (1) by 4/3πR3Cv we obtain:

dT(t)/dt =  W̃ T(t)/R                                                                                               (2)

where W̃=3W/(CvR3) is the specific power of the heating sources expressed in units of thermal capacity, and D̃ = 3D/Cv. The solution of  (2) is as follows:

            T(t) = T0 + (W̃R/)[1 - exp(-D̃t/R)]                                                                           (3)

Relationship (3) implies that temperature approaches its maximum value W̃R/ along the saturation trajectory, which we also observe in Figure 1. Instructively, the maximum possible temperature is proportional to R.  This fact is helpful and important for better understanding of our model. We interpret temperature as income, which one can reach using some physical capital, say 4/3πR3, and personal efforts, say W. Then the saturation curve in Figure 1 becomes an obvious result.

Above the age of peak mean income in Figure 1, one observes an exponential fall. Blue dotted line is defined by function exp[-0.052(t-56)]. It best matches the IRS curve above 56 years of age.  The match between the observed curve and the exponent is extraordinary even in terms of hard sciences. The exponential function is a well-known solution of a familiar equation: dx(t)/dt=-bx(t). The only difference is in the absence of term a, but now the curve starts from 1.0. Hence, the evolution of mean income measured by the IRS above the critical age can be expressed by a differential equation formally identical to that describing free cooling of a preheated sphere, i.e. when heating source W=0 in (1).

Hence, the observed features of the mean income behaviour are similar to those observed in a simple physical experiment. However, we need to describe income trajectory for each and every person in a given economy. It is natural to suggest that all individual incomes follow own saturation curves and their average value repeats some individual trajectory. Then the distribution of parameters defining individual trajectories, i.e. income analogues of R and W, is completely constrained by observations. This is the intuition behind our model.

Originally, the idea of income modelling with equation (2) came from geomechanics [Rodionov et al., 1982]. An identical equation describes the growth of stress, σ(t), in an inhomogeneous inclusion with characteristic size L experiencing deformation at a constant rate ε̇ as induced by external forces. Solution (3) is important to predict the highest possible level of stress at a given inclusion with size L. Unlike in the simple experiment with heated sphere of radius R, the sizes of inhomogeneous inclusions are distributed according to a power law L3dn/d(lnL) =const, where n is the number of inclusion of size L in a unit volume. This distribution defines a structural self-similarity of fractals.

In economics, higher incomes are characterized by a similar distribution, but they are the net result of all forces and agents in the economy not the predefined structure as in geomechanics. Moreover, low and middle incomes are distributed according to an exponential law rather than a power one.  So, we had to construct the basic distributions of defining parameters which result in the exponential distribution of low/middle income and power law distribution above the Pareto threshold. The process of model development with explicit differential equations together with the selection of underlying distributions is described in the following subsection.


No comments:

Post a Comment

Трамп: лидер, системный человек или безумец?

 Каждый человек, обладающий высшей государственной властью, должен разделять в уме три разных способности решать вопросы, относящиеся к долж...