Here, we revisit our stock
price model for Advanced Micro Devices (AMD) first presented in 2012.
The original model was obtained using our concept of share pricing. The intuition behind this concept is
simple; a faster growth in the CPI directly
related to the share price (e.g.
energy consumer price for energy companies) relative to some independent and
dynamic reference (e.g. some goods and services which price does not depend on
energy) should be manifested in a higher pricing power for the company. Our model selects (using the LSQ method) a defining CPI and the best reference
index from a set of 92 CPI with estimates started before 2000. This set is
fixed - it is important for model stability. Both CPIs for a given model must
define the studied price for at least 8 months in a row, i.e. the model has to
be the same for a relatively long time: the longer – the better. Mathematical details
are presented in Appendix.
We
have borrowed the time series of monthly closing prices of AMD from Yahoo.com
and the relevant (seasonally not adjusted) CPI estimates through February 2014
are published by the BLS. As in the
original model, the evolution of AMD share price is defined by the consumer
price index of rent of primary residence (RPR) and that hospital and related
services (HOSP); both indices are
shown in Figure 1. The defining time lags are as follows: the RPR index leads the
share price by 1 month and the HOSP by 5 months. The relevant
best-fit models (for 2011 and 2014) for AMD(t)
are as follows:
AMD(t) = -2.21RPR(t-1) – 0.82HOSP(t-5)
+ 37.87(t-1990) + 267.01, December 2011
AMD(t) = -2.16RPR(t-1) – 0.77HOSP(t-5)
+ 36.09(t-2000) + 625.65, March 2014
where AMD(t) is the AMD share price in U.S.
dollars, t is calendar time. Figure 2
depicts the high and low monthly prices for an AMD share together with the
predicted and measured monthly closing prices (adjusted for dividends and
splits). As a rule, the predicted prices are well within the bounds of the
share price uncertainty. The model
residual error is shown in Figure 3; the standard model error is $3.29 for the period
between July 2003 and March 2014.
All in
all, with the current trends in both defining CPIs retained over a longer
period AMD has no chance to recover to the 2006 level. It is hard to imagine
that the index of rent of primary residence will not be growing in the future.
All CPIs related to medical care, including HOSP, have stable linear time trends since the very
beginning.
Figure
1. Evolution of defining consumer price indices
Figure 2. Observed
and predicted AMD share prices.
Figure 3.
The model residual error.
Appendix
We introduced a simple deterministic pricing model in 2009 [1]. Originally, it
was based on an assumption that there exists a linear link between a share
price (here only the stock market in the United States is considered) and the
differences between various expenditure subcategories of the headline CPI. The
intuition behind the model was simple - a higher relative rate of price growth
(fall) in a given subcategory of goods and services is likely to result in a
faster increase (decrease) in stock prices of related companies. In the first
approximation, the deviation between price-defining indices is proportional to
the ratio of their pricing powers. The
presence of sustainable (linear or nonlinear) trends in the differences allows
predicting the evolution of the differences, and thus, the deviation between
prices of corresponding goods and services. The trends are the basis of a
long-term prediction of share prices. In the short-run, deterministic forecasting
is possible only in the case when a given price lags behind defining CPI
components.
In its general
form, the pricing model is as follows [2]:
sp(tj) = Σbi∙CPIi(tj-hi)
+ c∙(tj-2000 ) + d + ej (1)
where sp(tj) is the share price at discrete (calendar) times tj, j=1,…,J; CPIi(tj-hi)
is the i-th component of the CPI with
the time lag hi, i=1,..,I; bi, c and d are empirical coefficients
of the linear and constant term; ej
is the residual error, which statistical properties have to be scrutinized. By
definition, the bets-fit model minimizes the RMS residual error. The time lags
are expected because of the delay between the change in one price (stock or
goods and services) and the reaction of related prices. It is a fundamental
feature of the model that the lags in (1) may be both negative and positive. In
this study, we limit the largest lag to eleven months. Apparently, this is an
artificial limitation and might be changed in a more elaborated model. In any
case, a fourteen-month lag seems to be long enough for a price signal to pass
through.
System (1) contains
J equations for I+2 coefficients. We fix I=2.
To resolve the system, we use standard methods of matrix inversion. As a rule,
solutions of (1) are stable with all coefficients far from zero.
For the sake of
completeness we always retain all principal subcategories of goods and
services. Among them are the headline CPI (C),
the core CPI, i.e. the headline CPI less food and energy (CC), the index of food and beverages (F), housing (H), apparel
(A), transportation (T), medical care (M), recreation (R),
education and communication (EC), and
other goods and services (O). In this
model, we use 92 CPI components. They are not seasonally adjusted indices and were
retrieved from the database provided by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (2014).
There are two
sources of uncertainty associated with the difference between observed and
predicted prices. First, we have taken the monthly close prices (adjusted for
splits and dividends) from a large number of recorded prices: monthly and daily
open, close, high, and low prices, their combinations as well as averaged
prices. Without loss of generality, one can randomly select for modeling
purposes any of these prices for a given month. By chance, we have selected the
closing price of the last working day for a given month. The larger is the fluctuation
of a given stock price within and over the months the higher is the uncertainty
associated with the monthly closing price as a representative of the stock
price.
Second source of
uncertainty is related to all kinds of measurement errors and intrinsic stochastic
properties of the CPI. One should also bear in mind all uncertainties
associated with the CPI definition based on a fixed basket of goods and
services, which prices are tracked in few selected places. Such measurement errors are directly mapped
into the model residual errors. Both uncertainties, as related to stocks and
CPI, also fluctuate from month to month.
No comments:
Post a Comment