10/31/12

Crude and steel - an unbreakable pair

The price of iron and steel is likely to fall in October-December 2012 following the drop in oil price.  We have been reporting on the trade-off between the (not seasonally adjusted) producer price index of crude oil (domestic production) and the PPI of iron and steel since 2009. It has been always a linear and lagged link between them.  Here we present data through September 2012.

We first reported that the PPI of crude oil had been likely evolving in sync with that of iron and steel, but with a lag of two months in September 2009.  In order to present both indices in a comparable form, the difference between a given index, iPPI (i.e. iron and steel or crude), and the overall PPI was normalized to the PPI: (iPPI(t)-PPI(t))/PPI(t). These normalized differences represent the evolution of the rate of deviation from the PPI over years.  

Figure 1 depicts the corresponding time histories of the normalized deviations from the PPI, including the most recent period through September 2012.  Even a simple visual inspection reveals the following feature: the (normalized deviation from the PPI of the) index of iron and steel lags by approximately two months behind the (normalized) index of crude oil.


Figure 1. The deviation of the iron and steel price index and the index of crude oil from the PPI, normalized to the PPI.

In order to reduce both deviations to the same scale we additionally normalized the curves in Figure 1 to their peak values between 2005 and 2012.

(iPPI(t)-PPI(t))/[PPI(t)*max{iPPI-PPI)}]

This scaling allows a direct shape comparison. In Figure 2, we display the normalized index of iron and steel shifted by two months ahead to synchronize its peak with that observed in the normalized index for crude petroleum. The scaled index of crude demonstrates short-term deviations from the index of iron and steel in the overall shape and timing of the peak and trough. Simple smoothing with a three-month moving average, MA(3), makes the curves resemblance even better. As an extra benefit of the resemblance, one can use the two-month lag to predict the future of the iron and steel price index.




Figure 2. Deviation of the iron and steel price index from the PPI, normalized to the PPI and the peak value after 2005 as compared to the deviations of the index for crude petroleum normalized in the same way. The normalized index for iron and steel is shifted two months ahead. One can expect the index of iron and steel to fall relative to the PPI in October-December 2012.  

Conclusion
The link between oil and iron has been unbreakable. Between 2006 and 2012, the deviation of the price index of iron and steel from the PPI in the USA repeats the trajectory of the deviation of the index of crude petroleum (domestic production) with a two-month lag. Therefore, the prediction of iron and steel price for at this horizon is a straightforward one. From Figure 2, one can expect the price of iron and steel to fall relative to the PPI in October-December 2012 in line with the observed fall in oil price.

10/28/12

Krugman: denial of denial of denial of economics

Paul Krugman   will never surrender.  He insists that the economic theory  does give a good explanation of the current  economic trajectory. However, a half of economic profession does not support him (and the other half).  When I and many other scientists working in physics) deny the economic theory this is a "denial of economics". When Krugman denies our denial - this is a denial of denial. When the other half of  economists deny Krugman's opinion - this is a denial of denial of denial of economics. They do not deny economics as we do.

Comparison of personal income distributions reported by the IRS and Census Bureau


We have discussed many times in this blog that personal incomes are not well defined and the lack of a comprehensive definition does not allow any accurate estimate of income inequality. Here we compare two data sets for 2001. The IRS reported 128,227,145 people with the cumulative income of $6.37E+12. The Census Bureau (CB) found 221,591,000 people with the total income of $6.45E+12, with the working age population of 243,946,000. All figures published by the CB are obtained as a projection of about 200,000 people covered by the Current Population Survey to the working age population as a whole using so called population controls and thus the higher incomes with just few representatives are subject to large biases. The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) has estimated the personal income in 2001 as $8.89E+12. Therefore the IRS and the CB both reported only 72% of the gross personal income (GPI) as based on 53% and 87% of working age population, respectively. This BEA provides no personal income distribution (PID) and thus its data are worthless for the analysis of income inequality. The IRS and CB data sets are also not comprehensive since give two different and mainly independent slices of the personal income distribution. One might try to recover the overall PID from these data sets.

The IRS and CB provide PIDs in different income bins.  This excludes any direct comparison of the relevant PIDs.  The CB covers incomes between $0 and $250K with bins of $10K before and $50K above $100K. The IRS distribution spans the interval between $0 and $10M with the bin width varying from $1K to $5M. All incomes above $250K and $10M, respectively, are covered by open-end bins for which the width cannot be determined. We have calculated two probability density functions (PDF) for the IRS and CB by dividing their PIDs by the widths of income bins and total population. (We did not normalize to the total incomes because they are practically identical.) Figure 1 presents both PDFs. These curves represent the portion of total population in $1 bins as a function of income. Between $15K and $40K, the PDFs practically coincide. Below $15K, the probability density reported by the CB is higher, and above $40K the IRS curve is above the CB one. Both curves reveal a power law distribution above approximate $70K. This allows an extension of the CB curve above its limit of $250K with a power law function with the index of -3.34 as shown in Figure 2. From Figure 1, one can conclude that the excess of 93,000,000 of people in the CB’s PID is inherently related to low incomes. The IRS compensates the total income deficit associated with the lack of low-incomers by a larger portion of people with higher incomes. In that sense, the CB better covers the sources of low incomes and the IRS includes more accurate sources of incomes above $50,000.

In order to construct a comprehensive definition one should combine all sources on income over the whole income axis. The simplest way is to use the CB’s PID below and the IRS’ PID above some threshold. We have chosen the level of $75K because there are bins starting with this value for both the IRS and CB. The number of people reported by the IRS and CB with incomes above $75K is different: 19,452,000 and 15,218,000, respectively. The former number is more accurate since the IRS includes almost all sources of high incomes and we consider the joint (merged IRS/CB) distribution at high incomes to be that reported by the IRS. The extra 4,234,000 people with incomes above $75K might be counted in by the CB as having lower incomes. However, one cannot easily redistribute the CB’s PID by extracting these four millions. Therefore, we just added 4,234,000 to 221,591,000 reported by the CB in order to calculate the basis for the corresponding PDF. This is a crude approximation but it should not introduce a large bias in the lower income bins since it is less than 2% is added. At lower incomes, we use the CB’s PID. Figure 3 shows the new merged PID (black line) which includes 225,000,000 and $7,819B.  The total income in the merged distribution is closer (895) to the GPI.
 
Figure 1. PDFs for IRS and CB

Figure 2.  The high income PDFs for the IRS and CB. The actual CB PDF shown by red circles and is extended by a power law with the index of -3.34 as shown by yellow circles.  The highest two values reported by the IRS lie above the power law distribution and are shown by blue squares with red contour. The expected values are shown by yellow squares.  
 
Figure 3. The merged personal income distribution.  At lower incomes, we retained $5K bins instead of $10K in Figure 1. At higher incomes, the merged PID is parallel to that reported by IRS but is much lower because the normalization basis has been increased from 128M to 225M people.

10/27/12

When I'll buy the S&P 500 index


In April 2012, we predicted a drop in the S&P 500 to the level of 1300 by the end of May. Figure 1 shows the predicted behavior in April and May 2012, with the predicted segment shown by red line. We expected that the path observed in the previous rally would be repeated with the bottom points coinciding.  When this prediction realized, we invested, say, one unit at the average price 1320. The expected exit level was 1500 in October 2013.

Figure 1. The original S&P 500 curve (black line) and that shifted forward to match the 2009 trough (blue line). Red line – expected fall in the S&P 500: from 1400 in March to 1300 in May.
Figure 2 shows the evolution of the S&P 500 monthly closing price between May and August 2012. The S&P 500 closing level for August was 1430 and reached 1469 in the middle of September. This level provided a ten percent return over approximately 4 months. One can see that the observed level was far above the expected level (blue line). The return and the deviation from the expected level both made us think that this was the best time to exit. We sold the index on September 21 (1460) anticipating strong turbulence (economic, financial, and political) and an overall fall to 1375 at a few months horizon.  

Figure 2. Same as in Figure 1 with an extension between May and August.

Figure 3 shows the evolution of the S&P 500 monthly closing price in September-December 2012. The current level (October 26th) is 1411. We used it as a closing price for October and put the November’s level down to 1375. One can see that the red line intersects the blue curve. The previous history of the black and red lines intersection with the blue one makes us think that the time to enter the market (S&P 500 index) is approaching. We’ll definitely buy at 1350 to 1375 which is an expected level by the end of 2012.  This level guarantees another 140 to 170 points (10% to 12%) by the end of 2013.

Figure 3. Same as in Figure 1 with an extension between September and November 2012.

TRENDS AND FLUCTUATIONS IN PRICE OF CRUDE OIL AND MOTOR FUEL

We have revealed long term sustainable trends in the difference between producer price index for oil and the overall PPI. In the long run, one can foresee the direction of oil price trend which is crucial for investments. Moreover, there are many short-term price fluctuations around the trend which have large amplitudes and thus allow active speculations.  

In the beginning of 2009, we developed a model [1, 2] predicting the long-term price evolution for various subcategories of consumer and producer price indices as well as major commodities: gold, crude oil, metals, etc. The model was based on one prominent feature of the difference between consumer (producer) prices of individual components and the overall consumer (producer) price index. These differences are characterized by the presence of sustainable long-term (quasi-) linear trends. For many producer price indices, these trends are slightly nonlinear but still robust. They are observed in subcategories with varying weights in the CPI and PPI: meats [3], gold ores [4], durables and nondurables [5], jewelry and jewelry related products [6], and motor fuel [7].   

For major CPI and PPI subcategories, these trends last from five to twenty years and then turn to trends with opposite slopes. The transition to new trends lasted three years at most. We have not revealed any clear turns after 2009 and the current transition period might last longer. There are also several subcategories without slope changes since the start of the relevant measurement as reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics [8]. All CPI and PPI time series (in this study we use seasonally adjusted CPIs and not seasonally adjusted PPIs) were retrieved from the BLS. The best example of such a one-leg trend since 1980 is the consumer price index of medical care. The index of communication has been linearly deviating from the headline CPI since 1998; before 1998 it had been reported as an indistinguishable part of the index of education and communication. 

In the short run, actual prices oscillate around the long-term trends with varying amplitudes. In a sense, the trends represent the lines of gravity centers for given prices and any large deviation from the trends must be compensated promptly. As a result, both short- and long-term predictions of commodity prices are feasible. In the long run, the prices follow up the trends. In the short-run, the next move in a given price depends on the current position relative to the corresponding trend.  When far from the trend, the price is more likely to start returning. When approaching the trend, the price may choose any direction for the further evolution, i.e. it should not inevitably go the other side of the trend. In this article, we focus on crude oil and motor fuel.

For the price index of motor fuel, we developed a similar model as based on the deviation from the core CPI, i.e. the headline CPI less food and energy.  Using this model, we predicted the evolution of oil price as well. The overall performance of the model between March and December 2009 was reported in [9]. Here we also revise the long-term prediction of crude petroleum and motor fuel price and make necessary corrections to the model as related to the observations since March 2009.  

The model derived in [1, 2]  implies that the difference between the overall CPI (same for the PPI), CPI (PPI), and a given individual price index iCPI (iPPI), can be described by a linear time function over time intervals of several years:  

CPI(t) –  iCPI(t) = A + Bt       (1) 

, where A and B are the regression coefficients, and t is the elapsed time. Therefore, the “distance” between the CPI and the studied index is a linear function of time, with a positive or negative slope B. Free term A compensates the difference related to the start levels for a given year. For example, the index of communication was started from the level of 100 in December 1997 when the overall CPI was already at the level of 161.8 (base period 1982-84 =100).  

Figure 1 displays examples of linear trends in the two differences related to the scope of this article. In the left panel, the evolution of the index of motor fuel relative to the headline CPI is shown. Notice that in the original paper [7] we referred the index of motor fuel to the core CPI, but the discrepancy between the headline and core CPI is negligible relative to the change in the index of motor fuel.  There are two distinct periods of linear dependence on time: from 1980 to 1999 and from 2001 to 2008. Apparently, there is one finished transition period between 1999 and 2001, where the trend with a positive slope (B=+4.2) changed to a negative one (B=-21.1), in both cases the determination coefficient being very high: R2~0.89. The first transition period is characterized by elevated price volatility.  Since 2008, the negative trend in the difference has been suffering a transition to a positive one, which is shown in Figure 1 by a dashed line. This transition is characterized by a much higher volatility and has been fading away since the end of 2009. Without prejudice, we have drawn the new trend as increasing from -110 in 2009 to -60 in 2016. (Notice that we made a different tentative assumption in [10] since we had no actual data after 2009.) This defines the long-term prediction of the motor fuel index and fits observations since 2010.  

In the right panel, the difference between the PPI and the index of crude petroleum (domestic production) is shown between 1985 and 2012. There are two distinct periods of linear dependence on time: from 1988 to 1999 and from 2001 to 2008. The slopes of regression lines in both periods are different from those for the index of motor fuel: +2.9 and -17.9, respectively. There was one transition period between 1999 and 2001, where the original positive trend was turned down. We expect the difference to grow (the oil price index has to rise slower than the PPI) from -80 in 2009 to +20 in 2016; the growth rate is ~14 point per year. 
 
Figure 1. Illustration of linear trends. Left panel: the difference between the headline CPI and the index of motor fuel between 1980 and 2012. Right panel: The difference between the overall PPI and the (producer price) index of crude petroleum (domestic production). In both panels: there are two quasi-linear segments with a turning period between 1998 and 2001. Since the end of 2008, both differences have been passing a transition. Linear trends with relevant linear regression lines and corresponding slopes are also shown.

From Figure 1, one can conclude that the presence of linear trends is a basic feature of the CPI and PPI components which is likely to be repeated in the future. Another fundamental characteristic of the differences consists in the fact that all deviations from the trends were only short-term ones. This implies that any current or future deviations from the new trends in Figure 1, which have been under development since 2008, must be compensated promptly. This feature allows short-term (months) price predictions. 
Simple visual inspection of the transition period in Figure 2 shows that the difference in timing and amplitude between motor fuel and crude oil is not too big.  The amplitude of oil price fluctuations is higher since 2007 and especially during 2011 and 2012. In turn, the fluctuations in motor fuel price were slightly higher between 2000 and 2007.
  
Figure 2. Comparison of two differences.   

Figure 3 presents both differences after 2007. Overall, the evolution of the difference between the CPI and the index of motor fuel follows the new trend since 2011.  One may expect that after a few months below the trend (say, through October –December 2012) the next move will return the difference above the trend, i.e. the price of motor fuel will fall a bit relative to the CPI. In the long run motor fuel will be losing its pricing power relative to the CPI. The oil price prediction for 2013 is similar.  The difference in Figure 3 will reach the new (dashed) trend line and the oil price has to fall below $80 per barrel. 

Figure 3. Left panel: The difference between the headline CPI and the index for motor fuel.  Right panel:  Evolution of the difference between the PPI and the index for crude petroleum (domestic production).  Notice oscillations around the new trends.  

The forces behind the observed long- and short-term behavior are not accessible yet but very powerful. We may assume that they are fundamental and affect the economy to its roots. These forces retain equilibrium among all economic agents and originate the sustainable trends in the differences between consumer (producer) price indices. At some point, the forces meet their limits and should be re-balanced in order not to harm the economy. As a result, the trends in the CPI and PPI turn. 
Meanwhile, it is instructive to revise our long-term prediction of oil price shown in Figure 1. After a few minor adjustments to the initial and final levels of the PPI and the index of crude petroleum, Figure 4 depicts the revised prediction after 2010.  It is slightly different from our previous prediction with oil price in 2016 set between $30 and $60 per barrel. Short-term fluctuations cannot be predicted at a horizon of several years. However, the larger is a given deviation from the trend the larger is the returning force.
 
Figure 4. The evolution of crude oil price. Open circles represent the evolution of (monthly average) oil price for the period between 2001 and 2012.  Dashed lines – the upper and lower limits of the new trend between 2009 and 2016. According to the prediction, the price should fall to the level between $60 and $30 per barrel by 2017.  


10/26/12

Economists intentionally ignore 33,000,000 Americans when calculating income inequality


When discussing the increase in income inequality economists forget those people who have no income at all. According to the Census Bureau, there are tens of millions reporting no income every year and this number has been really growing since 1990 as Figure 1 shows. Notice also the dramatic fall in 1978, which was caused by a revision to income definition – more than 15,000,000 were added to income gainers in a few seconds.

The total population has been also growing by approximately 1% per year. Figure 2 depicts the ratio of the number if people without income and the total working age population (15 years of age and over).  This ratio has been growing since 1990 as well and there was no specific acceleration after 2007.  It is not clear why these people have been excluded by the Census Bureau from the reported measure of income inequality in the U.S. – the Gini ratio. Figure 3 displays three estimates of the Gini ratio. Black line presents the estimates published by the Census Bureau which are obtained for people with income only. Red line shows our estimates obtained from personal income distributions (PID) published by the Census Bureau.  The difference with the official figures between 1998 and 2011 is 0.011. This difference is likely related by the fact that we introduced a more accurate approximation of the PID in the lower and higher income bins. In any case, this difference is constant and negligible - one may correct any of the estimates by 0.011 and compensate the gap.  Therefore, we can use our method to estimate the Gini ratio and apply it to the PID including those without income.

When more than 30,000,000 people with zero income are added one should expect a dramatic increase in Gini ratio. Essentially, thirteen percent of working population adds to zero income what shifts the Lorenz curve further from the bisecting line. Blue line shows the estimates of Gini ratio for the whole working age population.  Unlike the red line, the blue line has been rising since 1990. The period after 2007 is characterized by an accelerated growth, which is obviously associated with the increasing number of zero-incomers. For people with income, the Gini ratio is rock solid over the whole period between 1967 and 2011 (with an almost negligible negative trend). Interestingly, there is no sign of the revision to income definition in 1977. Despite those 15,000,000 who were added in 1978 likely had negligible incomes they did not change the overall personal income distribution. This effect deserves a detailed investigation.

In terms physics, this is a mistake to neglect a substantial part of a closed system when calculating aggregate variables. Such aggregates are intrinsically biased and can not characterize the system and its behaviour.   Currently, the income inequality in the U.S. is much higher than the Census Bureau reports: the Gini ratio is rather 0.58.

Figure 1. The number of people without income according to the Census Bureau’s definition.
 
Figure 2. The portion of population without income

Figure 3. Three estimates of Gini ratio as described in the text.

How to describe and predict ConocoPhillips' share price

This article revisits our previous deterministic model for ConocoPhillips' (COP) share price. We present the underlying pricing concept, a quantitative model and several predictions. After the recent revision to COP's adjusted monthly closing prices, our model predicts at a three-month horizon. The uncertainty (standard deviation) of the prediction at a three-month horizon is $3.79 for the period between June 2003 and September 2012, with the RMS price change at the same horizon of $5.49. Since 2007, these values are $4.23 and $6.36, respectively. The accuracy of COP's price prediction (the uncertainty of the prediction is lower than the actual change) may serve as a solid basis for a substantial profit. We also give a prediction for the next three months.

Three years ago, we introduced a model based on the link between consumer and stock prices. We found a statistically reliable relationship between ConocoPhillips' stock price and the difference between the core and headline consumer price index (CPI) in the United States. It is instructive to revisit the original quantitative relationships with the relevant data available since 2009 in order to estimate them qualitatively and statistically. In this article, we focus on the evolution of ConocoPhillips' share price.

Originally, the agreement between the observed monthly closing price (adjusted for dividends and splits) and that predicted from the (seasonally not adjusted) CPI difference was relatively good and our tentative model covered the period between 1982 and 2009, which was split into two segments in order to match the turn in the trend observed in the CPI difference between 1998 and 2002.
The initial model based on two major CPIs was rather crude, however, and did not exercise numerous options associated with smaller CPI components directly connected to energy prices. We have investigated the whole S&P 500 list since 2009 and found hundreds of statistically robust quantitative models based on finer consumer price indices.

It would not be an exaggeration to conclude that the original approach has been significantly improved and the advanced models have shown a much higher predictive power, reliability and accuracy. Therefore, it is mandatory to apply the advanced approach to COP's stock.
Our pricing model assumes that the future of selected stocks is not unpredictable. Despite the inevitable bias of market participants, who are definitely convinced that all available information is already priced in, we have found many companies with stocks described by deterministic models based on various CPIs. This unaccounted information allows outperforming the market and its existence does not contradict common wisdom and scientific knowledge. There are true links between measured variables which we do not know yet.

 
Accordingly, there should exist many market features and processes currently inaccessible, but fully objective and describing the evolution of prices far beyond the contemporary market paradigm. Currently, there are many models and a huge number of tools related to stock pricing. Our pricing concept shows that these models and tools are likely of a limited usage only because they are constrained by the convention of price stochasticity and unpredictability. None of these ideas or techniques are borrowed and thus we omit usual review of the literature devoted to stock markets as irrelevant.

 
We have revealed many sustainable (quasi-) linear trends in the differences between consumer and producer price indices. At first, it was found that the difference between the core CPI, CC, and the headline CPI, C, can be approximated by a linear time function:

dCPI(t) = CC(t) - C(t) = A + Bt (1)

where dCPI(t) is the difference, A and B are empirical constants, and t is the elapsed time. Therefore, the distance between the core CPI and the headline CPI is a linear function of time, with a positive or negative slope B. Figure 1 displays this difference from 1960 to 2012. Both variables are not seasonally adjusted and are borrowed from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. There are three distinct periods of linear time dependence: from 1960 to 1980, from 1980 to 1998, and from 2002 to 2008. The second period is characterized by a linear trend with B=+0.67, and the third one has a larger negative slope of B=-1.58.



Figure 1. The difference between the core and headline CPI as a function of time. One can distinguish three periods of quasi-linear behavior with two distinct turning points. For the second and third periods, linear regression lines are characterized by slopes B=+0.67 and B=-1.58, respectively.  Solid green line represents the trend between 2009 and 2016 predicted as a mirror reflection of the previous trend, i.e. a straight line with B=+1.58.
Accordingly, there are two turning points or short transition intervals - between 1980 and 1981 and from 1999 to 2002. Since 2009, the difference has been passing the third turning point accompanied by a high degree of volatility. Similar behavior was observed between 1999 and 2002. In the past, the linear trends were very strong attractors to all deviations. Therefore, it is likely that in the near future a new linear trend will emerge, which may repeat the previously observed duration and slope.
In Figure 1, the green solid line represents the trend between 2009 and 2015 predicted as a mirror reflection of the previous trend between 2002 and 2008. Basically, the difference has to grow from 0 unit of index in 2009 to 11 units in 2016. In 2012, the actual value is close to zero.

Our approach to stock pricing is almost trivial. Imagine that one has to predict (describe) the evolution a share price for an energy company. It would not be a big mistake to assume that this share price is likely to be driven by the change in the overall energy price, which can be expressed by the price index including all energy prices (e.g. the headline CPI). Alternatively, some components of the overall energy category might be in play. Even if the studied company does not change its production the overall increase in the price of its product (and thus some consumer prices) should be manifested in its profit and higher (or smaller) share price.
On the other hand, when other prices (e.g. the core CPI) rise faster than the energy price index (say, 10% vs. 1% per year, respectively) one should not expect the energy company to gain extra pricing power. The company would rather suffer a share price decline. Thus, considering the secular increase in the overall price level, it is not the absolute change in energy prices that affects the stock price, but its current deviation from some energy independent price.

Without loss of generality, we have proposed to use the simplest model as based on the difference between the core and headline CPIs. No time lags between these indices were introduced in the beginning. (However, we allowed the stock price to lead the CPI difference.) We also ignored the sensitivity of the share price to the change in the core and headline CPIs and used them with the same weight of 1.0. When two defining CPIs evolve at quite different rates, one has to apply weighting, i.e. to introduce independent coefficients to both defining CPIs, in order to equalize their respective inputs.

The headline CPI includes all kinds of energy and thus provides the broadest proxy to the energy price index. The core CPI excludes energy (and food) and thus may represent the energy independent and dynamic reference. In the initial approach, we assumed the presence of a linear link between a stock price (COP) and the difference between the core and headline CPI: 
COP(t) = a + bdCPI(t + T) (2)
where a and b are empirical constants; T is the time delay between the stock and the CPI change, the CPI may lead or lag the price. Constants in (2) should be determined for each linear trend period separately. This implies the possibility of structural breaks in relationship (2) due to the turn to a new trend. One may suggest that any new trend manifests some deep structural changes in the overall economic behavior. Otherwise, there would be no change in the trends.
Three years ago, the evolution of ConocoPhillips' stock price was modeled as a linear function of the dCPI. Because we tested the general approach, only the trial-and-error method was applied and we sought for the overall visual fit between the observed and predicted prices, the latter is a scaled dCPI(t). In the original model, the best fit coefficients between 1998 and 2009 were as follows:
COP(t) = -6.0dCPI(t+2) + 80 (3)
The time lag of two months better fits the price fall in 2008. The slope was -6.0, i.e. the dCPI change by 1.0 has to be mapped into the price fall of $6. The intercept $80 implies that the long term level of COP price is $80 when dCPI=0.
In the beginning of 2012, we amended the original model and re-estimated all coefficients for the period between January 1998 and January 2012 using the LSQ method. The new model is as follows:
COP(t) = -5.35dCPI(t+1) + 72.3; σ=$7.87 (4)
where σ is the standard model error for the studied period. Relationship (4) is different from (3) and provides a slightly better overall fit. Figure 2 illustrates the predictive power of the model.

Figure 2. The predicted COP share price (red line), i.e. the scaled difference between the core CPI and the headline CPI from 1998 to 2012. Between 1998 and 2009 the historical prices for COP are shown by solid black line, and the period since 2009 with new data is shown by dashed line. 
When extrapolated in the past, i.e. before 1998, relationship (4) fails to predict the price as the red line in Figure 3 reveals. Judging from the discrepancy before 1998, one might wrongly suggest that the dCPI has no predictive power. Let's return to Figure 1, however, which shows that the linear trend before 1998 was positive and after 2002 - negative. Econometrically speaking, there was a structural break in the difference between the core and headline CPI. Hence, it would not be a big mistake to suggest that some inherent directions of pricing powers swapped between 1998 and 2002. It is reasonable to assume that the sign of slope in (4) before 1998 was opposite to that from 2002 to 2008. After reversing the sign and calibrating relevant amplitude and level between 1987 and 1998, we have obtained a much better fit, as shown by the green line in Figure 3, using the following function:
COP(t) = 2.2dCPI(t+1) - 7; 1987
Finally, a complete COP price prediction between 1987 and 2009 is obtained. Before 1987, the predicted curve in Figure 3 sinks below the zero line. There is no special need to describe the price in the early 1980s using the CPI difference. As shown here and here, all subcategories of the consumer price index, except the index of energy, are parallel before 1982. Therefore, the difference between any two indices, including the headline and core CPI, is constant, i.e. it contains no information on the changes in stock prices. This was the result of the CPI measuring procedures. New definitions and procedures were introduced between 1977 and 1982; they gave birth to numerous independently evolving CPIs.
Three years ago, we suggested the COP price will follow the new trend in the dCPI (green line) in Figure 1 with possible change in the slope sign. Figure 2 definitely shows that there has been no change in the sign since 2009 and likely no new trend has emerged. The turn has not happened yet. However, we are waiting for a turn to the new trend when oil prices will go down. On the other hand, the original model still works well and predicts larger movements in the price. Overall, our initial pricing model has matched the challenge of new data. The difference between the core and headline CPI gives a good approximation to the evolution of COP's price.
  
Figure 3.  The observed and predicted COP price. 

Figure 4. The difference between the observed and predicted time series. 
Figure 4 depicts the model error since 1998. There were periods of large deviations which all ended on the predicted curve. This effect allows formulating a hypothesis that any current deviation will return to the predicted curve which one may consider as a fundamental one. The most recent estimates show that the observed price has returned to its fundamental level after a short period of undervaluation. Potentially, this is a short-term investment idea.  The original model is crude, however, and we are looking for a better description with finer CPIs and PPIs.
The original model does not match high standards of quantitative modeling and statistical assessment. Both CPIs depend on many other goods and services, what introduces high measurement noise in the model. Also, both CPIs have the same weight (1.0) and cannot lead or lag behind the modeled price or each other.   Apparently, it can be some non-zero lag between the change in energy price and in prices of energy companies. Therefore, we have extended the model and described the evolution of a share price as a weighted sum of two individual consumer price indices (or PPIs) selected from a large set of CPIs. We allow both defining CPIs (PPIs) lead the modeled share price or lag behind it. Additionally, we introduced a linear time trend on top of the earlier introduced intercept. In its general form, the pricing model is as follows:
sp(tj) = Σbi∙CPIi(tj-ti) + c∙(tj-2000 ) + d + ej                       (6)
where sp(tj) is the share price at discrete (calendar) times tj, j=1,…,J; CPIi(tj-ti) is the i-th component of the CPI with the time lag ti, i=1,..,I; bi, c and d  are empirical coefficients of the linear and constant term; ej is the residual error, which statistical properties have to be scrutinized.
By definition, the bets-fit model minimizes the RMS residual error. The time lags are expected because of the delay between the change in one price (stock or goods and services) and the reaction of the other prices. It is a fundamental feature of the model that the lags in (6) may be both negative and positive. In this study, we limit the largest lag to thirteen months. Apparently, this is an artificial limitation and might be changed in a more elaborated model. In any case, a thirteen-month lag seems to be long enough for any price signal to pass through.
System (6) contains J equations for I+2 coefficients. Since the sustainable trends last more than nine years, the share price time series has more than 100 points. Due to the negative effect of a larger set of defining CPI components we limit the dimension to (I=) 2 in all models. To resolve the system, standard methods of matrix inversion are used.  A model is considered as a reliable one when the defining CPIs are the same during the previous eight months. The number and diversity of CPI subcategories is a crucial parameter.  In this study we progressively extend the set of defining components.

On May 1, 2012 our model for COP met an unexpected revision to the monthly closing price due to the fact that ConocoPhillips split into two companies (COP and Phillips 66). COP stock dropped by 22%. Figure 5 compares the old and new COP time series (both borrowed from Yahoo Finance), which are similar and can be scaled linearly with a factor of 1.36. Obviously, this change in the modeled time series has to result in new coefficients and likely lags in the new pricing models compared to those published before.
Figure 5. The change in the adjusted monthly closing price for COP.
So far, we have tested one principal pair of CPIs: C and CC. Now we try two more pairs:  CC and the index of energy, E, as well as the pair the PPI and the producer price index of crude oil, OIL. Since the COP closing price for September 2012 is available together with the estimates of consumer and producer price indices we model the period between June 2003 and September 2012, i.e. 112 months. The best fit model is obtained with the pair PPI and OIL (σ=$5.02):
COP(t)= 2.391C(t) – 3.231CC(t-10) + 4.339(t-2000) + 180.11; σ=$5.64   (7)
COP(t)= -1.372CC(t-0) + 0.481E(t) + 4.640(t-2000)  + 190.16; σ=$5.23  (8)
COP(t)= 0.728PPI(t-3) + 0.062OIL(t-0) – 2.54(t-2000) – 79.91; σ=$5.02   (9)
Figures 6 through 8 depict the observed and predicted monthly prices from (7) through (9).  In Figure 7, the advanced model based on the CPI of energy accurately predicts the COP price.  There was one major (negative) deviation from the predicted price in the fourth quarter of 2011. It ended on the fundamental price curve in January 2012. An investor could use the knowledge of the transient character of such a deviation and foresee the future return. Moreover, any large deviation likely gives a good investment idea.
Figure 6. Left panel: The observed (monthly closing) COP price and that predicted by relationship (7) from the headline and core CPI. The high and low monthly prices provide an estimate of uncertainty. Right panel: The model residual.


Figure 7. Left panel: The observed (monthly closing) COP price and that predicted by relationship (8) from the core and energy CPI. The high and low monthly prices provide an estimate of uncertainty. Right panel: The model residual.     
 Figure 8. Left panel: The observed (monthly closing) COP price and that predicted by relationship (9) from the overall and oil PPI. The high and low monthly prices provide an estimate of uncertainty. Right panel: The model residual.
            The next obvious step is to use a wider range of CPI and PPI components. Keeping in mind the inherent relation of ConocoPhillips to energy, we have selected the following indices:
C -                   the headline CPI;       
F -                    the consumer price index of food and beverages;    
H -                   the consumer price index of housing;
FU -                 the consumer price index of fuels and utilities (part of H);  
HHE -              the consumer price index of household energy;
CE -                 the headline CPI less energy;            
CC -                the core CPI;  
E -                   the consumer price index of energy;
MF -                the consumer price index of motor fuel;
GAS –             the producer price index of natural gas;       
COAL          the producer price index of coal;
EL –               the producer price index of electricity;  
OIL -               the producer price index of crude petroleum (dimestic production);
PPI  -              the overall PPI
All pairs of these CPIs and PPIs were used as defining parameters and the best model was obtained with the overall PPI and PPI of coal:

COP(t)= -0.532COAL(t-4) + 0.774PPI(t-3) + 5.331(t-2000) – 57.406; σ=$3.79  (10)
This model contains the same defining indices (PPI and COAL) as the model obtained before despite the change in the adjusted prices. The only difference is that the share price lags behind the PPI by four months and by three months behind the COAL. This means that the model predicts at a three month horizon. Figure 9 depicts the model and its error between 2003 and September 2012. The standard error is now only $3.79. This is a tremendous improvement, which is successfully accompanied by a smoother distribution of the error over time. The RMS error is a crucial characteristic of any model compared to the natural change over the predicted period. Therefore, we have estimated the RMS price change at the same horizon - $5.49.  Since 2007, the model error and the actual change are $4.23 and $6.36, respectively. The accuracy of the COP price prediction (the uncertainty of the prediction is lower than the actual change) may serve as a solid basis for a substantial profit. 
          Model (10) is the best among all studied models and has been also the best during the previous 8 months (see Table 1). In other words, the overall and coal PPIs give the smallest RMS residual since February 2012.    



Figure 9. Left panel: The observed (monthly closing) COP price and that predicted by relationship (10) from the overall and coal PPI. The high and low monthly prices provide an estimate of uncertainty. Right panel: The model residual. 
Table 1. The defining PPIs, lags and coefficients of the best fit models since February 2012.

Month
PPI1
Lag1
b1
PPI2
Lag2
b2
c
d
September
COAL
4
-0.5317
PPI
3
0.7739
5.3312
-57.4062
August
COAL
4
-0.5293
PPI
3
0.7762
5.2624
-57.6711
July
COAL
4
-0.5278
PPI
3
0.7769
5.2259
-57.7466
June
COAL
4
-0.5280
PPI
3
0.7769
5.2324
-57.7609
May
COAL
4
-0.5279
PPI
3
0.7769
5.2297
-57.7415
April
COAL
4
-0.5279
PPI
3
0.7769
5.2291
-57.738
March
COAL
4
-0.5283
PPI
3
0.7768
5.2389
-57.737
February
COAL
4
-0.528
PPI
3
0.7764
5.2121
-57.5463

Conclusion
We have estimated the best fit pricing model for COP with a three month predicting horizon. In October 2012, the next three months are expected to be associated with a growing COP price. This is the result of constant COAL price during three previous months and rising PPI. 

Трамп: лидер, системный человек или безумец?

 Каждый человек, обладающий высшей государственной властью, должен разделять в уме три разных способности решать вопросы, относящиеся к долж...