9/30/12

Political Calculations on recession in 2013

Ironman @ Political Calculations presented a measure which might indicate recession in 2013: the number of publicly-traded U.S. companies acting to cut their dividend payments each month.
A year ago, we presented a different measure showing a hightened probability of recession.
It seems that the change in populaiton is the reason for the companies to cut dividents.

Exploring Japan: on dismal perspectives of consumer prices

In this post, we continue to validate our predictions of the rate of consumer price inflation (CPI) in Japan by the estimate for 2011. The Japan Bureau of Statistics has estimated the rate of CPI inflation as -0.3%. Now we have an estimate of labour force for 2011 and are able to compare the observed and predicted  figures.  
We have been following inflation in Japan since 2005 when our first paper on the Japanese economy was published and covered the period through 2003. We have revisited inflation in Japan in 2010 and confirmed the predictions of deflation as expressed by the negative GDP deflator. In this blog, we also reported on deflation (both CPI and GDP deflator) several times.  
The case of Japan is the best illustration of our concept linking inflation to the change in labour force. (In a sense, all developed countries stay on the brink of deflation because of the threat of falling labour force.) Therefore we do not suggest the liquidity trap in Japan or any mistakes in monetary policy (inflation does not depend on monetary policy as our model shows.). The evolution of inflation is completely driven by the change in labour force. This is an unfortunate situation for Japan since the level of labour force can only fall in the long run due to the decreasing working age population.   
Previously, we carried out an estimation of empirical relationship between the change rate of labour force, dlnLF(t)/dt, and inflation, p(t).  
First, we test the existence of a link between inflation and labour force. Because of the structural (likely related to definition and measurement procedure) break in the 1980s, we have chosen the period after 1982 for linear regression. By varying the lag between the labour force and inflation one can obtain the best-fit coefficients for the prediction of CPI inflation, p(t),  according to the following relationship (updated with new data since 2009): 
p(t) = 1.39dlnLF(t-t0)/dt + 0.0004                                (1)
where the time lag t0=0 years; standard errors for both coefficients are shown in brackets.  Figure 1 (upper panel) depicts this best-fit case. (The period after 2003 is highlighted.) There is no time lag between the inflation series and the labour force change series in Japan. Free term in (1), defining the level of price inflation in the absence of labour force change, is statistically undistinguishable from zero.
A more precise and reliable method to compare observed and predicted inflation consists in the comparison of cumulative curves. Short-term oscillations and uncorrelated noise in data as induced by inaccurate measurements and the inevitable bias in all definitions should be smoothed out in cumulative curves. Any actual deviation between two cumulative curves persists in time if measured values are not matched by the defining relationship.
The predicted cumulative values shown in the lower panel of Figure 1 are very sensitive to the free term in (1). For Japan, the cumulative curves are characterized by complex shapes. There are periods of intensive inflation and a deflationary period. The labour force change, defining the predicted inflation curve, follows all the turns in the measured cumulative inflation.
One can conclude that relationship (1) is valid and the labour force change is the driving force of inflation. Statistically, the evolution of the overall level of consumer prices in Japan is fully defined by the change in labour force. Hence, no other variable or process can affect the change in price. Otherwise, the statistically reliable link would not exist.  
Having the projection of labour force borrowed from the National Institute of Population and Social Security Research, one can predict the future of CPI inflation in Japan. It will be decreasing to the level of -1% per year in 2050.  
Conclusion: invite immigrants and start a baby boom today! Otherwise, the level of consumer prices in 2050 will be a half of that of today.  
 
Figure 1. Measured inflation (CPI) and that predicted from the change rate of labour force. Upper panel:  Annual curves. Lower panel: Cumulative curves between 1982 and 2011. A good agreement between the cumulative curves illustrates the predictive power of our model.
 
Figure 2. Scatter plot: predicted vs. measured rate of CPI inflation.
Figure 3. Projection of the labour force evolution between 2005 and 2050.

Figure 4. The rate of CPI inflation in Japan through 2050.

9/29/12

Oil price in 2012-2013


This is a revision to our oil price prediction as based on the difference between the overall PPI and the index of crude oil. Figure 1 compares our previous prediction in May 2011 with actual oil price in 2011 and 2012. In August 2011, the predicted price was a bit higher than the measured one. We expected the price to fall by approximately $5 per month to the level of ~$70 by December 2011. In reality, the price reflected from the high bound of the expected price (dashed line) and grew during the end of 2011. This effect reflects the high level of price volatility during short time intervals. Since February 2012, the price has been returning to the expected price range which expresses the slow fall through 2016, with the uncertainty bounds for the long-term trend in oil price shown in Figure 1. The level of oil price in 2016 is expected between $30 and $60 per barrel.
Here we confirm the oil price trend and its bounds. Red squares show our prediction of oil price through February 2013. Despite local fluctuations, the trend is negative and will bring the price to $45 (±$15) per barrel in 2016.  
Figure 1. The evolution of oil price since 2001 as estimated from the differnce of the overall PPI and the PPI of crude petroleum.

CPI and core CPI. A half-year report


We have been routinely reporting on the difference between the headline and core CPI since 2008. Figure 1 illustrates our general finding that this deference can be well approximated be a set of linear trends. The last trend likely finished in 2009. That’s why we expected a new trend to evolve since 2010 into the late 2010s.
The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics has reported the estimates of various consumer price indices for August 2012. Figure 2 shows the predicted trend and the actual difference since 2010. The difference has been fluctuating around zero between June 2011 and  January 2012 and then showed a turn to the predicted trend.  Essentially, the zero difference suggests that the core and headline CPI are practically equal and evolve at the same monthly rate, i.e. the joint price index of energy and food has been following the price index of all other good and services (the core CPI) one-to-one.
Currently, the price index of energy slowly falls together with oil price. We expect them to fall deeper and thus the headline CPI to decelerate a bit together with energy. If the core CPI will retain its current cohesion with the headline CPI, we will have a period of very low inflation in all goods and services less energy and food. 

Figure 1. Two trends in the difference between the healine and core CPI.


Figure 2. The evolution of the difference between the core and headline CPI since 2002.

The effect of measuring procedure on Gini ratio estimates


The Census Bureau publishes Gini ratio for households as based on the Current Population Surveys conducted every March. Unfortunately, the CPS data are not compatible over time. (Actually, the CB mentions that in footnotes, but this is not the best place for general public and even for experts.) Therefore, the estimates of Gini ratio are biased and cannot be used in order to characterize the evolution of income inequality in the US. At the same time, each estimate is accurate to the extent the data and calculation procedures allow. Here we present the case of changing data granularity in 2009 which affected the estimates of Gini ratio for various household sizes.  

It is well known that the total income increases with time due to the increase in nominal GDP and population growth. The Census Bureau was measuring the household income distribution in $2500 bins with the upper limit of $100,000 since 1994. All households with income above $100,000 were counted in the open-ended ”$100,000 and above” bin. In 1994, there were 6,581,000 households in this bin and the portion of income was only 26%. This is not good for the Gini ratio estimation since one bin cover a quarter of all total income. In 2008, this bin accommodated 51% of total income. Such a bin counting is too crude and it makes the Gini ratio calculations almost worthless. Since the higher incomes are distributed according to the Pareto law, i.e. a power law, the CB can and does calculate the Gini ratio analytically for higher incomes.

In any case, the Census Bureau had to increase the bins to $5000 and the upper limit to $200,000 together with calculation of Gini ratio with bin counting up to $250,000 (the readings in the bins above $200,000 are not published!).   For the convenience of the CB, this change is appropriate. But it induced a step in the Gini ratio time series. Figure 1 displays the jumps for households of various sizes – from one person to seven+ people. Since households with more people have higher incomes one can expect that the portion of households with $100,000+ income increases with household size. The change in bin granularity and the upper limit from 2008 to 2009 has to change this portion and induce a step in the Gini ratio series.  Table 1 lists these portions for 2008 and 2009 as well as their ratios.

Table 1. The portion of households with income above $100,000 in 2008 and $200,000 in 2009.
2008
2009
ratio
One person
0.054
0.008
6.52
Two people
0.213
0.037
5.69
Three people
0.270
0.048
5.61
Four people
0.339
0.068
4.99
Five people
0.311
0.071
4.36
Six people
0.282
0.057
4.90
Seven people or more
0.278
0.053
5.20


We illustrate the step in Gini ratio using the overall income distribution. The overall Gini was calculated using the Pareto law approximation for the higher incomes and thus is not biased as the estimates of individual household sizes.  Figure 2 depicts three Lorentz curves based on the relevant CB estimates of household income distribution in 1994, 2008, and 2009. One can see a dramatic difference in Lorentz curves in 2008 and 2009. The high income bin with a half of total income makes the 2008 Gini ratio to be highly underestimated compared to the 2009 estimate. Both curves are identical for 85% of population, however. The 1994 curve also coincides with the 2009 one up to the last bin. Table 2 compares our estimates of Gini ratio and those reported by the CB. One can see that the 2008 CB estimate is corrected, but the step of 0.023 well reproduces the step observed for the individual household sizes in Figure 1.

Table 2. The estimates of Gini ratio in this post and those reported by the CB.
Gini ratio
CB Gini ratio
2009
0.466
0.465
2008
0.443
0.466
1994
0.457
0.456

 

Figure 1. The evolution of Gini ratio for individual household sizes. Notice the step between 2008 and 2009.

Figure 2. The Lorentz curves for household income distribution in 1994, 2008, and 2009, as constructed from the CB income distributions without approximation of the higher incomes by the Pareto law.

9/28/12

Crude and steel still in sync

We have been reporting on the trade-off between the producer price index of crude oil (domestic production) and the PPI of iron&steel since 2009. It has been always a linear and lagged link between them.  Our previous update included PPI data through March 2012. Here we present an annual wrap-up.

We reported that the PPI of crude oil had been likely evolving in sync with that of iron and steel, but with a lag of two months in September 2009.  In order to present both indices in a comparable form, the difference between a given index, iPPI (i.e. iron&steel and crude), and the overall PPI was normalized to the PPI: (iPPI(t)-PPI(t))/PPI(t). These normalized differences represent the evolution of the rate of deviation from the PPI over years.  


Figure 1 depicts the corresponding time histories of the normalized deviations from the PPI, including the most recent period through August 2012.  Even a simple visual inspection reveals the following feature: the (normalized deviation from the PPI of the) index of iron and steel lags by approximately two months behind the (normalized) index of crude oil.

Figure 1. The deviation of the iron and steel price index and the index of crude oil from the PPI, normalized to the PPI.

In order to reduce both deviations to the same scale we additionally normalized the curves in Figure 1 to their peak values between 2005 and 2012.

(iPPI(t)-PPI(t))/[PPI(t)*max{iPPI-PPI)}]

This scaling allows a direct comparison of corresponding shapes. In Figure 2, we display the normalized index of iron and steel shifted by two months ahead to synchronize its peak with that observed in the normalized index for crude petroleum. The scaled index of crude demonstrates just short-term deviations from the index of iron and steel in the overall shape and timing of the peak and trough. Simple smoothing with MA(3) makes the curves resemblance even better. As an extra benefit of the resemblance, one can use the two-month lag to predict the future of the iron and steel price index.

Figure 2. Deviation of the iron and steel price index from the PPI, normalized to the PPI and the peak value after 2005 as compared to the deviations of the index for crude petroleum normalized in the same way. The normalized index for iron and steel is shifted two months ahead.
 
Conclusion
The link between oil and iron has been unbreakable. Between 2006 and 2012, the deviation of the price index of iron and steel from the PPI in the USA repeats the trajectory of the deviation of the index of crude petroleum (domestic production) with a two-month lag. Therefore, the prediction of iron and steel price for at this horizon is a straightforward one.  

 

How the household split affects the household Gini ratio

The average household size has been decreasing since the start of measurements in 1967. Between 1994 and 2007, the average household size fell from 2.61 to 2.55, and the overall household Gini ratio increased from 0.456 to 0.463. In 2009, a new measuring procedure was introduced and all estimates of Gini ratio were subject to artificial corrections due to the change in data granularity and the overall coverage by income bins.
Here we argue that the change in Gini ratio results from the change in the household size distribution. We demonstrate the effect of the average household size on Gini ratio using the household size distribution measured in 2011.  This year is convenient since it covers with $5000-wide bins incomes up to $200,000.  This leaves 5,106,000 households from 121,084,000 in the income bin above $200,000.  The average household size in 2011 was 2.55. Figure 1 presents the distribution of households over sizes. One can calculate that with the given size distribution and average size, the mean size in the 7+ (seven and more people) group is 11.9 people.  
Figure 1. The distribution of households over sizes in 2011. Total number 121,084,00, with the average size 11.9 people in the 7+ group.
In order the average household size to decrease, bigger households should split and create an excess of smaller size households with lower incomes. As an alternative, a larger number of smaller households (with lower mean income) should be created. Both processes reduce the relative number of households with many people and increase the number of small-size households.  
Without loss of generality, we split all six people households with incomes below $100,000 into two equal households having a half-income. Therefore, instead of one six people household with $50,001 income we have two three people households with $25,000.5 income. These two households are now in the group of three people households with incomes between $25,000 and $30,000. One can expand this procedure to any household size and to any permutation of sizes. (For example, a six people household might be split into two households of 2 and 4 people, or three two-people households, etc.)  The only requirement is the same total income of the pieces. This process is linear and the final mean size is a function of all splits. Here we just demonstrate the principle. Figure 2 presents the original income distribution of six people households. Figure 3 depicts the original income distribution of three people households and that obtained after the split of all six people households in Figure 2 into equal (size and income) pieces.
Figure 2. Income distribution of six people households between $0 and $100,000.
Figure 3. Original (red) and corrected (blue) income distribution of three people households between $0 and $50,000.
We have split 1,953,530 households and obtained extra 1,953,530 households with the total number of 123,037,000 households.  The average household size decreased from 2.55 to 2.51 since bigger households were replaced by a larger number of smaller ones.
The total income does not change since all new households retain the income of split households. The income distribution has changed, however. When calculating the Gini ratio for the new income distribution we have to take into account the change in the mean income in all income bins between $0 and $50,000 due to additional three people households.
We have calculated the Lorenz curve (Figure 4) and then estimated the Gini ratio for the new income distribution. The original Lorenz curve (red) lies above the new one (blue). This is the reason why the Gini ratio is higher for the new income distribution: it increased from 0.4697 to 0.4746. This gives an increment of 0.005 as related to the 0.04 fall in the average household size (2.55 to 2.51).  Considering the overall decrease in the average size by 0.06 between 1994 and 2007, one may expect the Gini ratio rise by 0.0075. The actual figure is 0.007. Hence, the change in Gini ration can be fully explained by the change in the average household size.
Figure 4. The Lorenz curve for the original (red) and new (blue) income distribution.

9/27/12

The jump in Gini ratio in 2009 is fully artificial


Figure 1 depicts the evolution of Gini ratio for various sizes of households. We mentioned before that in 2009 there was a revision to the procedures and bins of household income measurements during the Current Population Survey.  One can see that there is a jump in all household sizes between 2008 and 2009. Effectively, this jump is fully artificial and there is no change between 2010 and 2011 as mentioned in blogs and academic papers.  Also notice that there was a fall in 2006 also induced by major revision in 2005. For all changes, the reader may check the Census Bureau web site.

All in all, the household Gini has not been really changing over time.

 Figure 1. The evolution of Gini ratio for various household sizes between 1998 and 2011.

Comparison of Gini ratios for various household sizes: 1998 vs. 2007.



In the previous post, we presented the difference in income distributions for household sizes from one person to seven and more people as observed in 1994 and 2007. Unfortunately, there are no Gini ratio estimates in 1994 for specific household sizes. The first year when the Census Bureau reported these estimates was 1998 and here we compare Gini ratios for 1998 and 2007 together with now standard presentations of normalized income distributions. We use 2007 because in 2009 the CB changed the width of income bins to $5000 and increased the high-end limit to $200,000. Therefore, the measurements before and after 2008 are not compatible. Since nominal GDP was higher in 2007 than in 2008 it is reasonable to use 2007 as a reference year.

Again, we do not repeat the technical part which was well described in this post. Briefly, we showed that the household Gini is biased up in 2007 relative to 1994 because the portion of smaller and thus lower income households increased. Accordingly, the average size decreased. To do this, we normalized the household income distribution to the total number of households and corrected the income bins to the total increase in nominal GDP and the change in the total number of households. This operation is similar to that used for the Lorenz curve calculation.


Figure 1 compares Gini ratios in 1998 and 2007. For all sizes except the one-person-households, the Gini ratio slightly fell since 1998. The increase in one-person households might be related to the increase in the portion of population without income (see this post). In any case, the claim of increasing income inequality among households is not supported by these observations. The dispersion of household incomes (with two or more people) has been decreasing. This is the change in size distribution what actually induced the reported increase in the overall Gini ratio. Since the data granularity increased in 2009, the upper open-ended interval for Gini calculations increased to $250,000, and the interpolation within income bins was changed to the Pareto law, one should not compare the years before and after 2008.


Figure 1. Comparison of Gini ratios in various household sizes: 1998 vs. 2007.

As in our previous post, Figure 2 compares the household income distributions (density functions).. There were relatively more small-size households with one and two people in expense of mid-income households of 3 and more people. Not having the 1998 Gini estimates, we may say that the Gini for the small-size households increased and accordingly decreased for the larger households. But the effect of changing dispersion (and thus Gini) in any household size is likely smaller than the effect of larger households split with the creation of an excess of smaller households.





Figure 2. The evolution of income distribution density functions in various household sizes.

9/26/12

The evolution of income inequality in households of various sizes


In one of our previous posts we addressed the issue of the household Gini ratio dependence on the average household size. We demonstrated that the Gini has not been increasing, as many economists say, but was actually constant as the Gini for personal incomes [1, 2].

We would not repeat the technical part of the post. Briefly, we showed that the household Gini is biased up in 2007 relative to 1994 because the portion of smaller and thus lower income households increased. Accordingly, the average size decreased.  To do this, we normalized the household income distribution to the total number of households and corrected the income bins to the total increase in nominal GDP and the change in the total number of households.  This operation is similar to that used for the Lorenz curve calculation. 

In this post, we present the evolution of income distribution in various household sizes and the same procedure as for the whole distribution. Unfortunately, there are no estimates of Gini ratio in all household sizes for 1994, but Figure 1 depicts these estimates for 2007. 



 

Figure 1. Gini ratio as a function of the household size in 2007.

Figure 2 compares the household income distributions (density functions) in 1994 and 2007. There were relatively more small-size households with one and two people in expense of mid-income households of 3 and more people.  Not having the 1994 Gini estimates, we may say that the Gini for the small-size households increased and accordingly decreased for the larger households. But the effect of changing dispersion (and thus Gini) in any household size is likely smaller than the effect of larger households split with the creation of an excess of smaller households.



Figure 2. The evolution of density functions in various household sizes. 

9/25/12

Young people are getting poorer in real terms

The Census Bureau reports (real and current) mean income in various age groups. Figure 1 presents the evolution of real mean incomes (in 2010 US dollars) normalized to the highest mean income, i.e.  to the mean income  in 2000 measured in the age group between 45 and 54 years (marked as 50 in Figure 1).
The mean income in the age group between 65 and 74 years has been healthy rising since 1987 (first reading available). In the youngest age group (from 15 to 24 years of age), there is no change since 1967. This observation is often discussed in blogs - poor youngsters.   
Actually, the situation is even worse.  The CB does not include people without reported income in the calculation of mean income. Figure 2 presents the portion of people with income in the same age groups as in Figure 1.  The portion of young people with income has been falling since 1978. I do understand that the Census Bureau has no responsibility for people without income, but to report 33,000,000 people as having no income puts the CB’s questionnaire under doubt.  There is no explanation why all those people have no income. More outrageous, there is no intention to include those sources of income which may resolve this issue. In terms of physics, the Census Bureau reports measurements of an open system, which may fluctuate with the changing portion of population.
In Figure 3, we correct the curves in Figure 1 for the portions without income.  Actually, the mean income has been falling since 2001. This effect has been explained in my book - Mechanics of personal income distribution: The probability to get rich.
Figure 1. The evolution of real mean income in various age groups normalized to the peak income of $54,177 (2010 US dollars) as observed in 200 in the age group between 45 and 54.
Figure 2. The portion of people with income in various age groups.

 

Figure 3. The evolution of mean income in the youngest age group, the original one and that corrected for the portion of people without income.  

Трамп: лидер, системный человек или безумец?

 Каждый человек, обладающий высшей государственной властью, должен разделять в уме три разных способности решать вопросы, относящиеся к долж...