3/31/11

A win-win monetary policy in Canada

We have published a working paper on structural breaks related to the introduction of  inflation targeting in Canada. The intuition behind the Lucas (1976) crituque is correct. The reader may enjoy the beauty, i.e. the simplicity and clearness,  of the integral approach. 

The paper is available on arXiv::

A win-win monetary policy in Canada

Abstract
The Lucas critique has exposed the problem of the trade-off between changes  in monetary policy and structural breaks in economic time series. The search for and characterisation of such breaks has been a major econometric task ever since. We have developed an integral technique similar to CUSUM using an
empirical model quantitatively linking the rate of inflation and unemployment to the change in the level of labour force in Canada. Inherently, our model belongs to the class of Phillips curve models, and the link between the involved variables is a linear one with all coefficients of individual and generalized models obtained by empirical calibration. To achieve the best LSQ fit between measured and predicted time series cumulative curves are used as a simplified version of the 1-D boundary elements (integral) method. The distance between the cumulative curves (in L2 metrics) is very sensitive to structural breaks since it accumulates true differences and suppresses uncorrelated noise and systematic errors. Our previous model of inflation and unemployment in Canada is enhanced by the introduction of structural breaks and is validated by new data in the past and future. The most exiting finding is that the introduction of inflation targeting as a new monetary policy in 1991 resulted in a structural break manifested in a lowered rate of price inflation accompanied by a substantial fall in the rate of unemployment. Therefore, the new monetary policy in Canada is a win-win one.

3/3/11

Modeling S&P 500 returns. March 2011

We restart (or continue) reporting on the evolution of the S&P 500 and our prediction made in the beginning of 2009. Between March 2009 and September 2010, the prediction based on the number of nine-year-olds, N9, fitted the observed S&P 500 with minor deviations. All in all, sixteen months in a raw we were right and did not see any source which might disturb our prediction. However, there is one source of problem for many economic and econometric models we have built – population distributions provided by the US Census Bureau.

Here, we reintroduce the original model which links the S&P 500 annual returns, Rp(t), to the number of nine-year-olds, N9. To obtain a prediction we use the number of three-year-olds, N3, as a proxy to N9 at a six-year horizon:

Rp(t+6) = 100dlnN3(t) - 0.23 (1)

where Rp(t+6)is the S&P 500 return at a six-year horizon. Figure 1 depicts relevant S&P 500 returns, both actual one and that predicted by relationship (1). The latter curve has been deviating the latter one since October 2010. Currently, this deviation is very big and put our model under strong doubt.



Figure 1. Observed and predicted S&P 500 returns.

This is not the end of the model, however. We continue using the link between real GDP and N9, as described in this paper. It was shown that one can exchange them when one of these two is not well estimated (usually N9). In that sense, one can use real GDP instead on N9.

As discussed in our working paper on S&P 500, there exists a trade-off between the growth rate of real GDP, G(t), and the S&P 500 returns, R(t). The predicted returns, Rp(t), can be obtained from the following relationship:

Rp(t) = 0.0062dlnG(t) - 0.01 (2)

where G(t) is represented by the Q/Q (annualized) growth rate, because only quarterly readings of real GDP are published by the BEA.

With a small correction of the coefficients in (2), Figure 2 displays the observed S&P 500 returns and those obtained using real GDP, as presented by the US Bureau of Economic Analysis. As before, the observed returns are MA(12) of the monthly returns. The period after 2003 is relatively well predicted, including that not predicted by (1). Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that G(t) can be used for modeling of the S&P 500 index and returns. Reciprocally, current S&P 500 may be used for the estimation of real GDP.

Figure 2. Observed S&P 500 return and that predicted from real GDP. For a given quarter, all monthly values of the growth rate relative to the previous quarter are equal.

To understand the deviation associated with N9 we are waiting for the final results of the 2010 census. This is also crucial for many economic models we have developed for the U.S. Other developed countries do not demonstrate such big deviations.

Turkey outperforms Germany economically in the 21st century

  Maddison project database ( MPD ) is a famous source of real GDP data for the whole world. Let's compare real GDP per capita for Turke...